版權(quán)說(shuō)明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請(qǐng)進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡(jiǎn)介
CanEnergySubsidiesHelpSlayInflation?
ChristopherErceg,MarcinKolasa,JesperLinde,
andAndreaPescatori
WP/24/81
IMFWorkingPapersdescriberesearchin
progressbytheauthor(s)andarepublishedto
elicitcommentsandtoencouragedebate.
TheviewsexpressedinIMFWorkingPapersare
thoseoftheauthor(s)anddonotnecessarily
representtheviewsoftheIMF,itsExecutiveBoard,
orIMFmanagement.
2024
APR
N
Ann
R
INTERNATIONALMONETARYFUNDii
?2024InternationalMonetaryFund
WP/24/81
IMFWorkingPaper
MonetaryandCapitalMarketsDepartment
ResearchDepartment
CanEnergySubsidiesHelpSlayInflation?*
ChristopherErceg,MarcinKolasa,JesperLinde,AndreaPescatori
AuthorizedfordistributionbyChristopherErceg
April2024
IMFWorkingPapersdescriberesearchinprogressbytheauthor(s)andarepublishedtoelicit
commentsandtoencouragedebate.TheviewsexpressedinIMFWorkingPapersarethoseofthe
author(s)anddonotnecessarilyrepresenttheviewsoftheIMF,itsExecutiveBoard,orIMFmanagement.
ABSTRACT:Manycountrieshaveusedenergysubsidiestocushiontheeffectsofhighenergypricesonhouseholdsandfirms.AfterdocumentingthetransmissionofoilsupplyshocksempiricallyintheUnitedStatesandtheEuroArea,weuseaNewKeynesianmodelingframeworktostudytheconditionsunderwhichthesepoliciescancurbinflation.Wefirstconsideraclosedeconomymodeltoshowthataconsumersubsidymaybecounterproductive,especiallyasaninflation-fightingtool,whenappliedgloballyorinasegmentedmarket,atleastunderempiricallyplausibleconditionsaboutwage-setting.Wefindmorescopeforenergysubsidiestoreducecoreinflationandstimulatedemandifintroducedbyasmallgroupofcountrieswhichcollectivelydonothavemuchinfluenceonglobalenergyprices.However,theconditionsunderwhichconsumerenergysubsidiesreduceinflationarestillquiterestrictive,andthistypeofpolicymaywellbecounterproductiveiftheresultingincreaseinexternaldebtishighenoughtotriggersizeableexchangeratedepreciation.Sucheffectsaremorelikelyinemergingmarketswithshallowforeignexchangemarkets.Iftheprimarygoalofusingfiscalmeasuresinresponsetospikesinenergypricesistoshieldvulnerablehouseholds,thentargetedtransfersaremuchmoreefficientastheyachievetheirgoalsatlowerfiscalcostandtransmitlesstocoreinflation.
JELClassificationNumbers:E32,E52,E64,H23,Q43
Keywords:
EnergyPrices;EnergySubsidies;MonetaryPolicy;InternationalSpillovers
Author’sE-MailAddress:
CErceg@IMF.org,MKolasa@IMF.org,JLinde@IMF.org,andAPescatori@IMF.org
*WethankTianchuQiandKailiChenforexcellentresearchassistanceandTobiasAdrian,JaebinAhn,GiovanniDell'Ariccia,Pierre-OlivierGourinchas,ZoltanJakab,andMathiasTrabandtforusefulcommentsanddiscussions.ThepaperalsobenefitedfromcommentsfromtheparticipantstotheCEPRParisSymposium,ESSIMinTarragona,NBU-NBPARCinCracow,CEFinNice,SummerWorkshoponEconomicsandFinanceinWarsaw,andseminarsattheEuropeanCentralBank,Bancad'Italia,andUniversityofOttawa.TheviewsexpressedhereareoursanddonotnecessarilyrepresenttheviewsoftheIMF,itsExecutiveBoard,orIMFmanagement.
1
1Introduction
Centralbankshavetightenedmonetarypolicyaggressivelytocombathighinflation,whichsurgedtomulti-decadepeaksinmanyeconomies.Whiletheinflationrunuphasbeendrivenbyanumberoffactors,includingsupplydisruptionsandmassivefiscalandmonetarystimu-lus,sharpincreasesinenergypriceshavebeenamajorcatalyst.Manycountriesrespondedbyusingvariousformsofenergysubsidies,oftentargetedmainlytohouseholds,tohelpcurb
inflationaswellastocushiontheeffectsonhouseholdpurchasingpower(Arreguietal.
,
2022
;
Sgaravattietal.
,
2023).Energysubsidiesareviewedbymanypolicymakersashelpful
inthefightagainstinflationonthegroundsthattheyarelikelytolimitbothfirstandsecondroundeffects,includingbyreducingpassthroughtowages.
Buttherearemanyopenquestionsabouttheconditionsunderwhichenergysubsidiesareactuallylikelytobeeffectiveinloweringinflation,or,conversely,whentheymaybecoun-terproductive.Whilewagestickinesshaslongbeenrecognizedaspivotalinthetransmissionofenergyshockstooverallpriceinflation(e.g.,
BlanchardandGali
,
2007),therehasbeen
littleanalysisofhowtheeffectsofenergysubsidiesoninflationdependonthemodalitiesofwage-setting,includingthedegreeofindexation.Similarly,itisunclearhowtheeffectsofsubsidiesdependonthestructureoftheenergymarket:couldinsulatingconsumersfromtheeffectsofhigherpricesinahighlysegmentedmarket–suchastheonefornaturalgasinEurope–hurtfirmsenoughtocausecoreinflationtorise?Andhowdotheeffectsofsubsidiesdependonwhethertheyareusedbyasingle“smalleconomy”orabroadsetofcountries?
Inthispaper,weuseaNewKeynesianmodelingframeworktohelpanalyzetheseques-tions,butfirstseekempiricalgroundingbyestimatinghowoilshockstransmittotheeconomyintheUnitedStates(US)andeuroarea(EA).Specifically,weuseaproxySVARapproachwheretheinstrumentisgivenbysurprisechangesinoilpricesfollowingtheannouncementofOPECmeetingdecisions.Theseriesofsurprisesisadoptedfrom
Ka¨nzig
(2021)andaggre
-gatedtoquarterlyfrequencyoverthe1983to2019sampleperiod.Fortheseidentifiedshocks,wefindthatanegativeoilsupplyshockwhichdrivesupthepriceofoilleadstohighercoreandheadlineinflation,lowerGDP,andhigherpolicyratesinitiallyinboththeUSandtheeuroarea.Importantly,wefindsignificantdifferencesinthetransmissiontowagesbetweenthesetwoeconomies,withoilpricehikeshavingsmalleffectsonnominalwagesintheUS–sothatrealwagesfallnotably–whereastheytendtoboostnominalwagesenoughintheeuroareathatthereal(product)wageactuallyrises.Thesedifferencesinwagetransmissionturnouttohavecriticalbearingonhowenergysubsidiesaffectinflation.
Turningtoourtheoreticalframework,webeginbyconsideringasimpleworkhorseclosedeconomymodelwithnominalwageandpricestickinessthatbuildson
Bodensteinetal.
(2011)
.Asinthatmodel,weassumetheeconomyhasanendowmentofenergythatisutilizedbothinproductionandconsumption,butenrichthesupplyblockbyallowingfor
2
alternativeformsofdynamicwageindexationwherewagesmayadjusttoeithercoreorheadlineinflation.Wealsoincorporateenergysubsidiesthatareproportionaltoenergyuse,thusresemblingthedominanttypeofsubsidiesintroducedinmanycountries,includingtheUSandEurope.
Usingthismodel,wedemonstrateformallythatprovidingenergysubsidiestoconsumersisessentiallyequivalenttotaxingenergyusebyfirms:bothpoliciesdecreasetheeffectiveenergycosttohouseholdswhileincreasingthatfacedbyfirms,thusresultinginthesameallocations
.1
Theimplicationisthatwhileconsumerenergysubsidiescanbedesignedtoshieldhouseholdsfromariseintherelativepriceofenergy(sayduetoasupplyshock),suchapolicyisessentiallyataxonfirmsthatdrivesuptheirmarginalcostsofproduction.
Weshowhowalog-linearizedversionofthemodelwithenergycanbeexpressedinaformisomorphictothatof
Ercegetal.
(2000),andusethisformulationtoderiveastriking
analyticalresult.Inparticular,weshowthatenergysubsidiestoconsumersnecessarilyboostcorepriceinflationifmonetarypolicykeepsemploymentatpotentialandwagesareindexedtocoreinflation(eitherfullyorpartially,includingthespecialcaseofnoindexation).Thisresultholdsforanyconfigurationofparametersassumingthatveryweakconditionsaresat-isfied(i.e.,implyingthatadverseenergyshocksreducethepotentialrealwage).Intuitively,whileconsumersubsidiesdamptheinitialriseinheadlineinflation,thesubsidiesdriveuptheenergypricesfacedbyproducers,whichtheypassalonggraduallythroughraisingproductprices.Hence,thesesubsidiesmakeinflation–bothcoreandheadline–morepersistent.
Theclosedeconomymodelisrelevantforconsideringthelikelyeffectsofconsumerenergysubsidiesintheglobaleconomywhenallcountriespursuesimilarpolicies,orinahighlysegmentedenergymarket(suchasfornaturalgasinEurope).Inshort,wefindusingquantitativesimulationsofourmodelthatevenahighdegreeofindexationtoheadlineconsumerpriceinflation–wellabovewhatwefindempiricallyfortheUS,oreventheeuroarea–isnotenoughforconsumerenergysubsidiestoreducecoreinflation.Thesesubsidiesindeedreducefirst-roundeffectsonheadlineinflationinresponsetoanenergypricespikeandthisreducesupwardpressureonwages,buttheyalsocausethepre-subsidyenergypricefacedbyfirmstoriseenoughthatthe“all-in”effectisariseincoreinflation.Welfareanalysisusingtheusualutility-basedmetricconfirmsthatconsumerenergysubsidieslowerwelfare.
Whileourworkhorsemodelcastsstrongdoubtontheabilityofconsumersubsidiestolowerinflationwhenappliedglobally,itstillmightbeexpectedthatasmallopeneconomy–orgroupofcountriestoosmalltoaffectglobalenergyprices–mightbeabletousesubsidiestolowerinflation.Toexplorethis,weuseatwo-countryextensionwithincompleteassetmarkets.Thisvariantallowsforthetransmissionofenergysupplyshockstodiffersubstantiallyacrossenergy-importersandexporters,andalsodependonthedepthofthe
1Thesealternativeapproachesdohavedifferentimplicationsforthepre-subsidyenergyprice,withtheconsumersubsidydrivinguptheenergyprice,andthetaxonfirmsdrivingitdown(hence,allocationswouldbeaffectedinasettingwithendogenousoilproduction).
3
foreignexchangemarketwhichheavilyinfluencestheexchangerateresponse.
Focusingonthesmallopeneconomycase,wefindmorescopeforconsumerenergysubsidiestoreducecoreinflationthanintheclosedeconomymodel.Thisseemsintuitive:suchsubsidiesshould“chokeoff”firstroundeffectsandthuslimitthescopeforsecondroundeffectstomaterialize,includingthroughwageindexation.Andfirmsshouldnotbe“bitten”byhigherglobalenergypricesgiventhehomecountry’ssmallshareintheglobalenergymarket.
Evenso,theconditionsunderwhichsubsidiesreducecoreinflationstillturnouttobesurprisinglyrestrictive.Althoughsubsidieshaveessentiallynoeffectonglobalenergyprices,theycausethetradebalancetodeteriorateandexchangeratetodepreciate.Thisexchangeratechannelcanbebigenoughthatsubsidiescancausecoreinflationtorise,unlesswageindexationtoconsumerpricesissufficientlyhigh.
2
Thedepreciationeffectislargerthemorepersistentthesubsidy(whichtypicallyislinkedtothepersistenceoftheunderlyingshocktoenergysupply)andislargerineconomieswithshallowforeignexchangemarkets,asisthecaseinmanyemergingmarketeconomies.
Thepolicyimplicationisthatconsumerenergysubsidiesmayhelpreducecoreinflationifimplementedbycountriesthatarearelativelysmallshareoftheglobalenergymarket;ifthesubsidiesaretemporary;ifwageindexationtoconsumerpricesishigh(sothatsecondroundeffectswouldbelargeintheabsenceofsubsidies);andiftheactionsaretakenbyeconomieswithwell-developedfinancialmarketsandmodestdebtlevels.Theseconditionsalignwellwiththosethat
Daoetal.
(2023)foundinthecaseoftheeuroarea,wheretheyarguethat
consumerenergysubsidieshelpedmitigatebothheadlineandcoreinflationpressures
.3
Butasforeshadowedbytheclosedeconomyresults,ourtwocountrymodelhighlightshowconsumersubsidiesarelesslikelytobeeffectiveinreducinginflationastheirusebecomesmorewidespread.Thepre-subsidyenergypricerisesbymore,makingitmorelikelythatsubsidiesboostinflation.Moreover,ourmodelhighlightstheadversespilloverstootheren-ergyimporters–thelatterexperiencebiggertradedeficits,currencydepreciation,andupsideinflationpressure.Thespilloversareparticularlyacuteforvulnerableemergingeconomieswiththinforeignexchangemarkets.
Whileourfocusislargelyonaggregatesupply,consumerenergysubsidiesalsohavedemandsideeffectsthatmayvarysignificantlyacrosshouseholds,andwhicharenotwell-capturedbyourframework.Indeed,ourwelfareresultsinparticularmaybeviewedasundulybiasedagainstsuchsubsidiesinsofarthemodeldoesnotallowforhowsubsidiesmayshieldpoorerandliquidity-constrainedhouseholdsfrommajorhitstotheirpurchasingpowerandconsumptionarisingfromenergyshocks–whichwasclearlyakeyaimofpolicymakers
2Energysubsidiestendtobehelpfulundertheseconditionsbychokingofffirst-roundeffectsthatwouldotherwiseexertlargepassthroughtocore.
3Wealsoshowthatapackageofenergysubsidiestofirmsaswellashouseholdsmaybeattractiveforasmall“energy-pricetaking”economy–supportingaggregatedemandwhileloweringinflation.
inadditiontorestrainingoverallinflation.
Toexplorethis,weincorporatehand-to-mouthhouseholdsintoourclosedeconomymodelasinthetwo-agentNewKeynesian(TANK)setupdevelopedby
Galietal.
(2007)and
Bilbiie
(2008),andshowthatourresultsarelargelyrobustevenwhencapturingthedemand-sideef
-fectsofenergyshocks.
4
Interestingly,weshowthatconsumerenergysubsidiescouldimprovewelfareinourTANKframeworkbyreducingconsumptioninequalityacrosshouseholds(i.e.,permanentincomeversushand-to-mouth).However,targetedtransferstohand-to-mouthhouseholdsaremoreefficientastheycanachievethisgoalatlowerfiscalcostandwithabetterinflation-outputtradeoff.Themainadvantageofsuchtransfersoverenergysubsidiesisthattheydonotdistortrelativeenergypricesfacedbyhouseholds,andhencepreservetheirincentivetoconserveenergy.Thislimitstheincreaseinthepre-subsidyenergypricefacedbyfirms,andhencelowersinflationpressure.
Ourpaperiscloselyrelatedtoaninsightfulrecentpaperby
Auclertetal.
(2023)which
exploresthetransmissionofoilshocksinanopeneconomyHANKmodel,andtheeffectsofconsumerenergysubsidies.Theseauthorsalsoshowhowsubsidiesmaybebeneficialinreducinginflationandboostingconsumptionforanindividual“small”country,butcanhavecounterproductiveeffectsifdeployedbyabroadsetofcountries.Ourpaperdiffersfromtheirworkinseveralimportantaspects.First,theirpaperfocusesheavilyonheterogeneityacrosshouseholdsinaHANKframeworkandassociateddistributionaleffects,whereasourstudydevotesmuchmoreattentiontothesupplyside(differentwageindexationschemesratherthanassumingfullindexationofwagestoconsumerprices).Second,weincorporatefeaturesaimedatcapturingfinancialvulnerabilities(suchasthinFXmarkets)thatinfluencehowsubsidiesoperatethroughopeneconomychannels.Third,weassumethecentralbankfollowsoptimalpolicyorusesaTaylor-stylereactionfunctionthatprovidesagoodapproximation.Thisturnsouttohaveimportantimplicationsforthepass-throughofenergypriceshocksandsubsidies.Alltold,ourpaperismorepessimisticintheabilitytouseconsumerenergysubsidiessuccessfullytoreduceinflation,eveninthecaseofasmallgroupofcountries(e.g.,showinghowsubsidiescanbecounterproductivethroughtradechannels).
Ourpaperalsodrawsontheextensiveearlierliteraturestudyingthetransmissionofen-ergypriceshocks.Keyempiricalcontributionsinclude
Hamilton
(1983),
Hamilton
(2003),
BarskyandKilian
(2004),
BlanchardandGali
(2007),
Kilian
(2009),
BaumeisterandHamil-
ton
(2019),and
Ka¨nzig
(2021)
.Weuseenergysupplyshocksidentifiedinthislastpapertoanalyzethereactionofwages.Anumberofpapersincorporateenergyintostructuralmacroeconomicmodels,butdonotstudytheeffectsofenergysubsidies,see
KimandLoun-
gani
(1992),
BackusandCrucini
(2000),
LeducandSill
(2004),
Bodensteinetal.
(2011),
BlanchardandRiggi
(2013),
Bodensteinetal.
(2018),
BaqaeeandFarhi
(2019),
Gagliardone
4DebortoliandGali(2018)arguethatasimpletwo-agentNewKeynesian(TANK)modelcanbea
goodapproximationofheterogeneousagentNewKeynesian(HANK)modelsregardingthetransmissionof
aggregateshockstomacroeconomicvariables.
4
5
andGertler
(2023),and
Pieroni
(2023),amongothers.Similarlyto
Auclertetal.
(2023),the
lastpaperusesaHANKsetupwhileweoptforamoreparsimoniousTANKmodelasanextensiontocapturehouseholdheterogeneityandanalyzethescopefortransfers.BylookingattheinteractionsbetweenpriceandnominalwagerigiditywithinNewKeynesianmodels,ourworkisrelatedtotheliteratureoriginatedby
Blanchard
(1986)anddrawsparticularly
on
Ercegetal.
(2000)and
Bodensteinetal.
(2008).
Arecentcontributioninthislineby
LorenzoniandWerning
(2023)considersboththetransmissionofsupplyanddemandshocks
andoptimalpolicyinacontinuoustimeframework(withinflationinterpretedasarisingfromconflictbetweenfirmsandworkersoverwages).
Thepaperisstructuredasfollows.Section2discussestheempiricalevidenceontheeffectsofenergypriceshocks,withaspecialfocusontheresponseofwages.Section3presentsasimpleclosedeconomymodelwithenergy.Section4offersanalyticalinsightsonthetransmissionofenergypriceshocksandsubsidies.ThesearecomplementedwithquantitativesimulationsdescribedinSection5.Section6presentstheversionofthemodelwithhand-to-mouthagentsandisfollowedbyanopeneconomyextensioninSection7.Section8concludes.
2EmpiricalEvidenceonOilShocksandWageAdjustment
Inthissection,weprovideempiricalevidenceontheresponseofwagesandconsumerpricestooilpriceshocksintheUnitedStatesandtheeuroarea.
First,weidentifyasourceofoilpricemovementsthatisnotcorrelatedwithotherfun-damentalshockstoavoidreversecausalityoraomittedvariablebias.Todoso,werelyon
Ka¨nzig
(2021)whoidentifiessurprisechangesinoilfuturespricesrelatedtoOPEC’s
meetingsdecisionsaboutproductiontargets.AsKnzigmeasuresthesechangesinatight
windowaroundtheannouncements,
5
itislikelythattheycanisolatetheimpactonoilpricesoftheunexpectedcomponentofOPEC’sdeliberations–analogouslytotheliteraturethatidentifiesmonetarypolicyshocks(e.g.,
Gurkaynaketal.,
2005;
GertlerandKaradi,
2015;
NakamuraandSteinsson,
2018,amongothers).SincemarketspaycloseattentiontoOPEC’s
decisions,areversecausalityoftheglobaleconomicoutlookshouldplausiblyberuledoutbecauseitshouldalreadybepricedinatthetimeoftheannouncement.OPEC’sdecisions
arenotrandomeventsbutastheKnzigshocksmeasureonlythecomponentnotanticipated
bymarkets,theirimmediateimpactonpricesshouldreflecttheelementofthedecisionthatsurprisedmarketparticipants
.6
Adistinctadvantageofusingtheseshocksrelativetothe
5Thewindowistakentobeoneday,usingWTIcrudefuturesstartingin1983tradedattheNewYorkMercantileExchange(NYMEX),whichisoneofthemostliquidandlargestmarketforcrudeoil.Forfurtherdetails,see
Ka¨nzig
(2021)
.
6NazerandPescatori
(2022)showthatitisthesurprisecomponentoftheOPEC(orOPEC+)decisions
thataffectsthemarketsincethesamedecisioncaninducepriceresponsesofdifferentsign.
6
standardapproachpioneeredby
Kilian
(2009)istobypassthedifficultiesofdisentangling
oildemandandoilproductionshocks.Evenso,wewillshowthatourresultsalsoholdwhenusingshocksmeasuredby
BaumeisterandHamilton
(2019)
.
Theseriesofoilpricesurprisesspanningfrom1983to2019areaggregatedatquarterlyfrequencyandusedasaninstrumentinanSVARmodel.Inadditiontothestandardoilmarketvariablessuchasrealoilprices(deflatedbyeithercoreorheadlineprices),oilproduction,andglobalindustrialproduction,ourproxySVARmodelalsoincludesrealGDP,coreorheadlineCPIinflation,theshort-termpolicyrate,aswellasnominalwageinflation.Allquantitiesandrelativepricesareinlogs,thepolicyratesinpercentagepoints,whilepriceandwageinflationaremeasuredaslogdifferences.WeuseidenticalSVARspecificationsfortheUSandtheeuroarea.Appendices
A.1
and
A.2
containadditionaldetailsontheproxySVARanddatadefinitions.
OurbaselineresultsarereportedinFigures
1
and
2
fortheUSandeuroarea,respectively.AccordingtotheproxySVARfortheUS,anincreaseinoilpricesdrivenbyanoilsupplynewsshockleadstoadeclineinnominalandrealwages.
7
Moreconcretely,anoilsupply-driven10percentincreaseinoilpriceswitha2-yearhalflifeincreasescoreinflationbyabout0.1percentagepointforafewquartersandreducesthenominalwagebyabout0.2percentonimpact.Consequently,theimpliedproducerrealwage–calculatedbyaccumulatingthenominalwagegrowthimpulsesandsubtractingtheaccumulatedcoreinflationimpulses–fallsbyroughly0.3percentoverthefirst2yearsandbynearly0.6percentafter5years.ThereductioninrealwagesisinlinewithanoilsupplyshocktransmittingsimilarlytoanadverseTFPshock,withrealGDPfallingbymorethat0.4percentafter2years.Cruciallyforourfurtheranalysis,theseresultssuggeststhattheabilityofUShouseholdsandlaborunionstoachievecompensationforhigherpricesthroughhigherwagesisverylimited.
TheimpactontheeuroareaisshowninFigure
2.
WhiletheoilpricepathisalmostidenticaltothatobtainedintheSVARfortheUS,thetransmissiontootherkeymacrovariablesdiffersnotably.Mostnotably,nominalwagegrowthpersistentlyincreases.ThisfindingispossiblydrivenbymorecentralizedwagebargainingandhigherunionizationintheeuroareathanintheUS,leadingtoahigherdegreeof(explicitorimplicit)indexation
(BabaandLee,
2022)
.IncreasingwagesputsomeupwardpressureoncoreinflationandsotheECBraisestheinterestratesignificantly.ThetighterpolicystanceimpliesthattheassociatedoutputcontractionisaboutthesameasintheUS,althoughtheeuroareaeconomyislessdependentonoil.Turningtotheimpliedrealproducerwage,thepointestimateofitsimpulseresponseismodestlypositive,butnotsignificantlyso.WeinterpretthisfindingasonlymildevidenceinfavorofsomeindexationmechanismsinEuropeanwagesettingthatcompensateshouseholdsforthelossofpurchasingpowerduetoenergypriceshocks.
7Theconfidencebandsarecomputedusingamovingblockbootstrap,asproposedby
JentschandLunsford
(2019).Thismethodproducesasymptoticallyvalidconfidencebandsunderfairlymildalpha-mixingcondi
-tions.Theblocksizeissetto24anddealswiththedifferenceintheestimationandidentificationsamples.
7
Figure1:USProxy-VAREvidence:OilPriceShocks
Notes:Allvariablesareexpressedinpercentdeviations,realoilpricesaredeflatedwithcoreCPI,impliedrealwageisdefinedasaccumulatednominalwageinflationminuscoreinflation.Theconfidencebandsarethe68and90percentlevelbandsbasedon10,000bootstrapreplications.
8
Figure2:EAProxy-VAREvidence:OilPriceShocks
Notes:Allvariablesareexpressedinpercentdeviations,realoilpricesaredeflatedwithcoreCPI,impliedrealwageisdefinedasaccumulatednominalwageinflationminuscoreinflation.Theconfidencebandsarethe68and90percentlevelbandsbasedon10,000bootstrapreplications.
AsshowninAppendix
A.3
,theimpactofanoilsupplyshockonheadlineinflationisnotablystrongeronimpactinboththeUSandtheeuroarea,upto1(0.5)percentinthe
9
samequarterbutmuchlesspersistent–consistentlywithoilpricesrevertingtotheirpre-shocklevels.Evenso,theimpliedconsumerrealwage,i.e.nominalwagedividedbyheadlineCPI,fallsnotablymoreinitiallythantheproducerrealwageinFigure
1
.Thesmallerpass-throughtoheadlineinflationrelativetocoreinflationintheeuroareathanintheUScanbeatleastpartiallyexplainedbyhigherexcisetaxesonliquidfuelsandadownstreamoil
industrythattendstohavemorerigidretailprices(Ahn,
2024).Importantlyforourfurther
analysis,regardlessifweworkwithcoreorheadlineinflationintheSVAR,wefindthattheimpliedrealwageintheeuroareafallslessthanintheUS.
WehaveexaminedtherobustnessofourresultsforanumberofalternativeSVARspec-ifications.Figure
3
presentstheimpulseresponsesfortheimpliedproducerrealwage(USintheleftcolumnandeuroareaintheright),whileAppendix
A.3
reportstheresultsforallvariablesincludedineachoftheconsideredalternatives.ThefirstrowinthefigurejustrestatesourbaselineresultsfromFigures
1
and
2.
Thesecondrowreportsanalternativewhereweimposemeanreversionoftherealwageimpulseresponsesbyintroducingthisvari-abledirectlyintheSVARinsteadofnominalwagegrowthandimposingstabilityconditions.Ascanbeseen,realproducerwagesintheUSstilldeclinesignificantlyinresponsetoanenergysupplyshockwhiletheyrisesomewhat(althoughnotsignificantlyatthe90percentconfidencelevel)inEurope.
Wealsotestedforpossiblenon-linearitiesintracingtheeffectsofoilpriceshoc
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無(wú)特殊說(shuō)明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁(yè)內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒(méi)有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒(méi)有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文庫(kù)網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 2025年度航空貨運(yùn)延誤責(zé)任保險(xiǎn)合同范本
- 2025年度海域使用權(quán)轉(zhuǎn)讓合同樣本2025年度
- 2025年度航空航天設(shè)備維修合同范文
- 二零二五版儲(chǔ)罐拆除工程環(huán)保驗(yàn)收與評(píng)估合同3篇
- 2025年度短視頻廣告設(shè)計(jì)制作與短視頻平臺(tái)合作合同
- 2025版國(guó)際貿(mào)易法實(shí)務(wù)操作指南合同
- 2025年度農(nóng)產(chǎn)品質(zhì)量安全監(jiān)管購(gòu)銷(xiāo)合同范本
- 2025年度護(hù)理行業(yè)人才儲(chǔ)備與培養(yǎng)合同
- 2025年度合同法規(guī)定之重型貨物運(yùn)輸合同標(biāo)準(zhǔn)范本
- 2025年度國(guó)際智能交通管理系統(tǒng)采購(gòu)合同
- 小學(xué)數(shù)學(xué)分?jǐn)?shù)四則混合運(yùn)算300題帶答案
- 林下野雞養(yǎng)殖建設(shè)項(xiàng)目可行性研究報(bào)告
- 心肺復(fù)蘇術(shù)課件2024新版
- 大型商場(chǎng)招商招租方案(2篇)
- 2024年交管12123學(xué)法減分考試題庫(kù)和答案
- 臨床下肢深靜脈血栓的預(yù)防和護(hù)理新進(jìn)展
- 2024年山東泰安市泰山財(cái)金投資集團(tuán)有限公司招聘筆試參考題庫(kù)含答案解析
- 英語(yǔ)主語(yǔ)從句省公開(kāi)課一等獎(jiǎng)全國(guó)示范課微課金獎(jiǎng)?wù)n件
- 年度工作總結(jié)與計(jì)劃會(huì)議
- 醫(yī)保按病種分值付費(fèi)(DIP)院內(nèi)培訓(xùn)
- 近五年重慶中考物理試題及答案2023
評(píng)論
0/150
提交評(píng)論