




版權(quán)說(shuō)明:本文檔由用戶(hù)提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請(qǐng)進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡(jiǎn)介
ContentsExecutiveSummary?/?iIntroduction?/?1TheModelandDebtDynamicsintheBaseCase?/?4AnalysisofAlternativeFiscalAnchors?/?8RankingtheFiscalAnchors?/?17Conclusions?/?20Appendix1:TheEquationsoftheModel?/?21Appendix2:EconometricModeloftheEffectsofGovernmentSpendingandTaxationonEconomicGrowth?/?23References?/?27Abouttheauthors?/?30Acknowledgments?/?31Publishinginformation?/?32SupportingtheFraserInstitute?/?33Purpose,funding,andindependence?/?33AbouttheFraserInstitute?/?34EditorialAdvisoryBoard?/?35?/?vvi?/?ExecutiveSummaryThecurrentandprojectedfiscalpoliciesofCanadiangovernmentsasawholeareunsustainable,withthenetdebttoGDPratiosteadilyincreasingto131percentin2050inourbasecaseprojection.Whilethereisuncer-taintyaboutfuturetrendsinthekeyfiscalvariables,suchasthegrowthrateofhealthcarespending,Canadiangovernmentsshouldbegintoadoptfiscalanchorsorrulestopreventanincreasingdebt-to-GDPratioovertime.Adoptingfiscalrulesthatcontainaclearcommitmenttosustainablefiscalpolicieswillhelpreducetheeconomicuncertaintythatadverselyaffectsprivatesectorsavingsandinvestmentdecisions,thebiastowardsdeficitsfinancingpublicexpenditures,andtheadoptionofpro-cyclicalfiscalpoliciesthatcanexacerbatetheeconomicfluctuations.Skepticismabouttheusefulnessofgovernmentsadoptingfiscalrulesiswarrantedbe-causeinthepastthefederalandprovincialgovernmentshaveabandonedsuchruleswhentheybecamebindingorimposeddifficultfiscalchoices.However,studiesbytheIMFhaveshownthatgovernmentsthathaveadopt-edfiscalruleshavestrongerfiscalpositionsandmorestablefiscalpolicies.Inthispaper,weevaluatethreefiscalanchorsthatCanadiangov-ernmentscouldadopt—adebtreductiontarget,aceilingontheratioofinterestpaymentstorevenues,andabalancedbudgetrule—balancingtheprimarybudgeteitherthroughexpenditurerestraintortaxincreases.Wesimulatetheadoptionofthesefiscalanchorsusinganeconomicmodelinwhichgovernments’fiscalpoliciesaffectthegrowthrateoftheecon-omyandtherealinterestrateonpublicdebt.Eachscenariohasdifferentimplicationsforgovernmentdebtratios,economicgrowthrates,andrealinterestratesongovernmentdebtfrom2025to2050.Werankthesealternativefiscalanchorsbasedontheirpotentialforprovidingbothpublicandprivategoodsandservicesandincometransfersoverthe25-yeartimehorizonofthemodels.Wefindthatachievingandthenmaintainingaprimarybudgetbalancethroughexpenditurerestraintisthebestfiscalanchorbecauseitwouldallowforbothmoreprivateconsumptionandhigherpublicexpendituresinpresentvaluetermsthananyoftheotherfiscalanchors.Similarly,thedebttargetanchorwouldbepreferredtoaceilingontheratioofinterestpaymentstorevenues,whichinturnwouldbepreferredtobalancingtheprimarybudgetthrough?/?iii?/?AnEvaluationofThreeAlternativeFiscalAnchorsforCanadaincreases.Whilethisrankingofthefiscalanchorsisbasedonthepar-ticularscenarioswehaveinvestigated,wefeelthatitwouldberobusttoalternativestrategiesforimplementingthesefiscalrules.Werecognizethatmaintainingaprimarybalanceraisesimportantimplementationissues.Strictadherencetoazeroprimarybalancecouldleadtoabruptandwastefulincreasesinprogramspendingduringaneco-nomicboomwhenthereisasurgeingovernmentrevenues,orabruptandharmfulcutsincurrentandcapitalspendingwithadownturnintheecon-omyandadeclineintaxrevenues.Toavoidpro-cyclespendingthatwouldcontributetomacroeconomicfluctuations,governmentscanadoptarulethatplacesaceilingonthegrowthrateoftheirexpenditures.Therangeofexpenditurestobecoveredbytheceilingshouldbebroad,coveringthosecurrentandcapitalexpendituresthatthegovernmentcancontrolinthemediumterm,butnotincludeexpendituresthathaveacyclicalcompo-nent,suchasunemploymentinsuranceorsocialassistancepayments.Ourmainresult—thatfiscalconsolidationbasedonexpenditurere-straintprovidesbettereconomicoutcomesthanpoliciesthatrelyonhigh-ertaxes—isconsistentwiththeconclusionreachedbyAlesina,Favero,andGiavazziintheirpioneeringstudy,Austerity:WhenItWorksandWhenItDoesn’t,of200episodesoffiscalausterityin16OECDcountriesfromthe1970sto2014.Theyconcludedthat“onaverage,expenditure-basedadjust-mentshaveconsistentlymuchlowercoststhantax-basedones…”ThisisalessonthatCanadiangovernmentsshouldheedwhentheyconsiderthefiscalpoliciesthatarerequiredtoputCanada’spublicfinancesonasus-tainablepathintheaftermathoftheCOVID-191.IntroductionCountriesaroundtheworldincurredunprecedentedfiscaldeficitsinresponsetothepandemic.Withtheresultingincreaseinpublicsectordebts,governments,internationalfinancialinstitutions,andthinktankshavestartedtoconsidernewfiscalanchorsorrulesthatshouldguidegovernments’fiscalpoliciesinthefuture.Tobeeffective,afiscalanchormustconstrainagovernment’sfiscalchoicesaffectingdebt,deficits,expenditures,orinterestpayments.Aclearcommitmenttosustainablefuturefiscalpolicieshelpsreducetheeconomicuncertaintythatadverselyaffectsprivatesectorsavingsandinvestmentdecisions.Itmayalsoreducethebiastowardsfinancingpublicexpendituresthroughdeficits,whichcanthreatenthelong-termsustainabilityofagovernment’sfinances,ortheadoptionofpro-cyclicalfiscalpoliciesthatcanexacerbatetheeconomicfluctuations.Insomejurisdictions,afiscalrulemayhelptolimitaper-ceivedpoliticalbiastoexcessivespendingandtaxation.AccordingtotheIMF,fiscalrulesshould(a)promotelong-termfiscalsustainability;(b)helpstabilizeeconomicactivitybyrestrictingpro-cyclicalfiscalpolicies;(c)applytofiscalvariablesthatareunderthecontrolofthefiscalauthority;(d)provideagovernmentwithreasonableoptionsforaddressingthefiscalsituationwhentheruleisbinding;and,betransparentsothattheycanbeunderstoodbythepublic,arenotsubjecttomanipulationorcreativeaccounting,arecoherent,andareap-pliedtobroadcomponentsofthebudget.1Aboveall,Eyraudetal.(2018b:4)stressthatfiscalrulesshouldbesimple,flexible,andenforceable.Themostcommonfiscalanchoristheratioofagovernment’sdebttotherelevantjurisdiction’sannualGrossDomesticProduct(GDP).Over70countrieshaveadoptedaceilingonpublicdebtaspartoftheirfiscalrules.TheEUhasrecentlyrevisedandmademoreflexibleitsfiscalrulesforitsmembercountriesnowthatallofthemajoreconomieshavedebt-to-GDPlevelsinexcessofthe60percentlimitthatwasestablishedintheGrowthandStabilityPactin1997(Blanchardetal.,2021;EuropeanCommission,2022).InCanada,priortothepandemic,thefederalgovernmenthadadoptedafiscalanchorofmaintainingadebt-to-GDPratioofcloseto30SeeDahlby(2021)ontheselectionoffiscalrulesinA?/?12?/?AnEvaluationofThreeAlternativeFiscalAnchorsforCanadapercent(Canada,DepartmentofFinance,2019:ChartA1.11).Currently,thefederalgovernmentisonlycommittedtoreducingthedebt-to-GDPratio(DepartmentofFinance,2022,p.58).Alberta’sgovernmenthassetagoalofkeepingitsnetdebt-to-GDPratiobelow30percent.Skepticismabouttheusefulnessofgovernmentsadoptingfiscalrulesiswarrantedbecausethefederalandprovincialgovernmentshaveaban-donedsuchruleswhentheybecamebindingorimposeddifficultfiscalchoices.2However,studiesbytheIMFhaveshownthatfiscalrulescanwork.3Initsoverallassessmentoftheefficacyoffiscalanchors,Eyraudetal.(2018b)concludedthatfiscalrulesare“correlatedwithstrongerfiscalpositionsandmorestabilizingpolicies”(p.12)andthat“eventhoughfiscalrulesarenotapanacea,theycanmakeadentintothedeficitbiasdepend-ingoncountrycircumstancesanddesignfeatures”(p.16).Inthispaper,weevaluatethreefiscalanchorsthatCanadiangovern-mentscouldadopt—adebtreductiontarget,aceilingontheratioofinter-estpaymentstorevenues(akaDodge’sRule),andabalancedbudgetrule—usingamodelinwhichgovernments’fiscalpoliciesaffectthegrowthrateoftheeconomyandtherealinterestrateonpublicdebt.WerunthemodelforabasecasescenarioinwhichCanadiangovernments’fiscalpoliciesareunsustainablebecauseofanever-increasinggovernmentdebt-to-GDPratio.Wethenexaminescenariosinwhicheachofthesefiscalanchorswouldbeimplementedtoachieveasustainablefiscalpolicy.Eachofthesefiscalanchorsresultsinadifferentpathfortaxrates,publicexpenditures,governmentdebtratios,andeconomicgrowthratesoverthe25-yearper-iodprojectedbyourmodel.Torankthefiscalanchors,wecomparetheirprojectedpublicexpendituresandhouseholdconsumptionspendinglevelsoverthis25-yeartimehorizon.Onthisbasis,weconcludethatbalancingtheprimarybudgetthroughexpenditurerestraintisthepreferredfiscalanchorbecauseitwouldallowformoreprivateconsumptionandhigherpublicexpenditures,inpresentvalueterms,thantheotheranchors.Simi-larly,thedebttargetanchorwouldbepreferredtoDodge’sRuleofkeepingtheratioofinterestpaymentstorevenuesbelow10percent,whichinturnwouldbepreferredtobalancingtheprimarybudgetthroughtaxincreases.Thepaperisorganizedasfollows.Section2providesanoverviewofthestructureofthemodelandasimulationofthekeyfiscalandeconomicvariablesinthebasecase.(Appendix1containsthemodel’sequations.Ap-pendix2describesoureconometricmodeloftheimpactoffiscalvariablesForexample,theAlbertagovernmenthasadoptedandthenabandonedsevendifferentsetsoffiscalrulessince1992.SeeSimpsonandWesley(2012)andTapp(2013)ontheimpactoffiscalrulesinCAnEvaluationofThreeAlternativeFiscalAnchorsforCanada?/?3oneconomicgrowthinCanada,whichisthesourceofthekeyparametervaluesourmodeluses.)InSection3,wedemonstratehoweachofthesefiscalanchorscouldbeimplementedandtheirimpactsondebtratios,eco-nomicgrowthrates,andrealinterestrates.Section4discussesourrank-ingofthefiscalanchors,andSection5summarizesourTheModelandDebtDynamicsintheBaseCaseWebeginwithabriefdescriptionofthemodelthatweusetoevaluatethefiscalanchors.(SeeAppendix1forthemodel’sequations.)Theinitialvaluesofthefiscalvariablesinthemodelarebasedonthevaluesforthefederal,provincial,territorial,andlocal(FPTL)governmentsectorinCanadacirca2019.ItisimportanttonotethattheFPTLsectordoesnotincludetheCanadaPensionPlan(CPP),theQuebecPensionPlan(QPP),andothersocialsecurityfundsthatareincludedintheIMF’sdefinitionof“generalgovernment.”WeexcludetheCPPandQPPbecauseanyfiscalanchorsadoptedbyCanadiangovernmentswillgenerallynotapplyto,orincorporatethefinancesof,theCPPandQPP,whosefiscalparametersarebasedonmaintainingthelong-runviabilityofthepublicpensionsystems.WealsofocusontheaggregateFPTL,ratherthanthefiscalvariablesforthefederalgovernmentoraparticularprovinceorterritory,becausewebelievethatitisimportanttoconsidertheoverallviabilityofpublicsectorfinancesinCanadaratherthanfocusingonanyoneofthe14governmentsonitsown.Weusethemodeltoprojectthegrowthrateoftheeconomy,therealinterestrateongovernmentdebt,andthedebtratiooftheFPTLsectorfrom2025to2050.4FourbehaviouralparametersinthemodeldeterminetheimpactofchangesincurrentandcapitalexpendituresbygovernmentsandtaxratesonthegrowthrateoftheCanadianeconomy.Theseparam-eterestimatesarebasedontheeconometricmodelofthedeterminantsofeconomicgrowthinCanadadescribedinAppendix2.Themodelhasthestandardpropertyofaneo-classicalgrowthmodelinthatfiscalpolicyshocksaffectthegrowthrateoftheeconomyintheshorttomediumterm,buttheeconomyeventuallyreturnstoitslong-termpotentialgrowthrate.Theeconometricmodelindicatesthatadebt-financedincreaseingovern-SeeDahlby,Ferede,andFuss(2022)foranoverviewoftrendsinCanadianeconomicgrowthrates,realinterestrates,primarybudgetbalances,andgovernmentdebt-to-GDPratios.4?/?AnEvaluationofThreeAlternativeFiscalAnchorsforCanada?/?5mentconsumptionspendingreducesthegrowthrateoftheeconomy,whileanincreaseincapitalspendingincreasesthegrowthrateintheshorttomediumterm.Similarly,anincreaseintaxrateslowersthegrowthrateoftheeconomyintheshorttomediumterm.Anotherkeyparameterinthemodelistherelationshipbetweenthegovernmentdebtratioandtherealinterestrateongovernmentdebt.Anumberofeconometricstudies,whicharereviewedbyDahlby,Ferede,andFuss(2022),indicatethattheinterestrateongovernmentdebtin-creasesasthegovernmentdebt-to-GDPratioincreases.Consistentwiththisliterature,inourmodeltheinterestrateongovernmentdebtincreasesbythreebasispointsforaonepercentagepointincreaseintheFPTLdebt-to-GDPratio.Inthebasecasescenario,governmentconsumptionexpendituresareinitially22.0percent,governmentcapitalexpendituresare5.0per-cent,andtransferstopersonsandbusinessesare10percentofGDP.Taxrevenuesare30percentandotherrevenuesare5.0percentofGDP.Thismeansthat,initially,thereisaprimarybudgetdeficitof2.0percentofGDP,orapproximately$1,450percapitain2025.Governmentcurrentex-pendituresongoodsandservicesandcapitalexpendituresareassumedtoincreasefrom2025to2050accordingtotheprojectionsinthePBO(2021)fiscalsustainabilityreport.Initiallytheinterestrateongovernmentdebtisabout3.0percentandtheinflationrateis2.0percent,implyingarealinterestrateongovernmentdebtofapproximately1.0percent.Theinitialnetdebt-to-GDPratiois70percentfortheFPTLsector,andtheratioofinterestpaymentsonnetdebttorevenueis6percent.Itisassumedthatlong-runannualgrowthrateofrealGDPis1.8percent,whichwastheaverageprivatesectorforecastpriortothe2020pandemic(Canada,De-partmentofFinance,2019:TableA1.1).Thus,thedifferentialbetweentherealinterestrateongovernmentdebtandthegrowthrateoftheeconomy,whichdeterminestheprimaryfiscalbalancethatisrequiredtostabilizethedebtratio,is-0.82percent.Figure1showsthetrajectoriesofthedebt-to-GDPratio,theeco-nomicgrowthrate,therealinterestrateongovernmentdebt,theratioofinterestpaymentstorevenues,andtheprimarybudgetbalanceoverthe25-yearperiodinourbasecasescenario.Programexpendituresincreasefrom37.0percentofGDPto37.9percent,basedontheprojectedincreas-esinexpendituresinthePBO(2021)fiscalsustainabilityreport.Withtheincreaseindeficit-financedgovernmentexpenditures,theannualgrowthrateoftheCanadianeconomydeclinesfrom1.80percentto1.74percentfrom2033to2046beforeslightlyrecoveringto1.76by2050.Governmentrevenueisfixedat35.0percentofGDP,andtheprimarydeficitincreasesfrom2.0percentto2.9percentofGDP.Asaresult,thedebt-to-GDP6?/?AnEvaluationofThreeAlternativeFiscalAnchorsforCanadaFigure1:BaseCaseFiscalandEconomicTrends1A:BaselineofNetDebt-to-GDPofFPTLSector,2025to2050140ofGDP120100Percent806040200
1B:BaselineRealInterestRateandEconomicGrowthinCanada,2025to20503.0RealInterestRate2.5GrowthRatePercent2.01.51.00.50.01C:BaselinePrimaryBudgetBalanceofFPTLSector,2025to2050-1.8ofGDP-2.0-2.2Percent-2.4-2.6-2.8-3.0
1D:BaselineRatioofInterestPaymentstoRevenueforFPTLSector,2025to205020181614Percent121086420Sources:PBO(2021);calculationsbyAnEvaluationofThreeAlternativeFiscalAnchorsforCanada?/?7increasesfrom70percentto131percent.Withtheincreaseinthedebt-to-GDPratio,therealinterestrateongovernmentdebtincreasesfrom0.98percentto2.7percent.Asaresult,thegapbetweentheeconomicgrowthrateandtheinterestratedeclines,andafter2040theinterestrateongovernmentdebtexceedsthegrowthrateoftheeconomy,whichalsocontributestotherapidincreaseinthedebt-to-GDPratio.Finally,theratioofinterestpaymentstogovernmentrevenuesincreasesbecauseofhigherinterestratesandhigherdebt-to-GDPratiosandexceeds10percentafter2039.ThefiscalpolicyoftheFPTLsectorisunsustainableinthebasecasescenariobecausethedebtratioisconstantlyincreasing.Thisconclu-sionisconsistentwiththeresultsofthePBO(2021)fiscalsustainabilityreportandalsowithLaurinandDrummond’s(2021)projectionsoftheincreaseinfederalandprovincialgovernments’netdebt.5Whilethereisuncertaintyaboutfuturetrendsinthekeyfiscalvariables,ourbasecasescenariomeansthatCanadiangovernmentsneedtoadoptnewfiscalpoli-ciestopreventanincreasingdebt-to-GDPratioovertime.Inthefollowingsection,weconsiderthreealternativefiscalanchorsdesignedtopreventexplosivegrowthinthepublicdebt.SeealsoTombe(2022)forafiscalsustainabilitysimulationtoolontheFinancesoftheNationwebsite.TheParliamentaryBudgetOfficer’s2022reportcontainsamoreoptimisticfiscaloutlookthanits2021reportbasedonrecentbudgetplanswhichhaveimproved“themedium-termoutlookforprovincialandterritorialgovernmentown-sourcerevenues”P(pán)BO(2022:5).Wefeelthatamoresanguinelong-termfiscaloutlookisnotjustifiedbasedononeyearofmoreoptimisticrevenueprojectionsandcontinuetousethePBO’s2021expenditureprojectionsfrom2025to2050inourscenarioswhereAnalysisofAlternativeFiscalAnchorsThreecommonlyproposedfiscalanchorsinthepublicfinanceliteratureare(1)atargetdebt-to-GDPratio,(2)adebtpayment-to-revenueratio,and(3)abalancedbudget.Afourthfiscalanchor,agovernmentprogramexpendituregrowthraterule,canbeusedinconjunctionwiththeotherrules.Inthissection,wedemonstratehoweachofthesefiscalanchorscouldbeimplementedandtheirimpactsonthedebt-to-GDPratio,eco-nomicgrowthrates,andrealinterestratesbasedonthemodeldescribedintheprevioussection.Atargetdebt-to-GDPratioPriortothepandemic,thefederalgovernmenthadeffectivelyadoptedafiscalanchorofmaintainingadebt-to-GDPratioofcloseto30percent.Inresponsetothepandemic-relateddeficits,someeconomists,suchasLester(2021)andRobsonetal.(2022),haveadvocatedfiscalpoliciesthatwouldreturnthefederalnetdebt-to-GDPratiotopre-pandemiclevels.Inthissection,weinvestigatetheimpactofadoptingadebttargetasafiscalanchor.Fourpolicychoicesneedtobemadeinselectingareduc-tioninthedebtratioasafiscalanchor.Oneisthetargetratio.Asnoted,intheinitialequilibrium,theFPTLnetdebt-to-GDPratioisprojectedtoreach70percentin2025.Theincreaseinthedebt-to-GDPratioresultingfromthepandemicwasapproximately20percentagepoints.Accordingly,wesimulateascenarioinwhichtheFPTLsectorhasatargetdebt-to-GDPratioof50percent.Asecondkeypolicychoiceishowrapidlytobringthedebt-to-GDPratiodowntothetargetlevel.Giventhatwearesimulatinga20-percentagepointreductioninthedebt-to-GDPratio,weassumethatthedebttargetistobeachievedwithin10years.Athirdpolicychoiceiswhethertheadjustmentwillbethroughataxincrease,anexpenditurereduction,orsomecombinationofthesetwomeasures.Inthescenariosummarizedbelow,weassumethatallofthefiscaladjustmentoccurson8?/?AnEvaluationofThreeAlternativeFiscalAnchorsforCanada?/?9theexpendituresideofthebudgetandthatthetax-to-GDPratioremainsfixedatitsinitialvalueof30percent.Afourthkeypolicychoiceiswhetherthegovernmentcutsconsumptionspending,capitalspending,orboth.Inthisscenario,weassumethatFPTLsectorgovernmentscutconsumptionandcapitalexpendituresinthesameproportion,eventhoughinstitutionalconstraints,suchasunioncontracts,andthedesiretoprotectkeypublicservices,suchashealth,education,andsocialservices,oftentiltthepolit-icalcalculusinfavourofcapitalspendingcutswheretheconsequencesarelonger-termbutlessobvioustothepublic.Giventherelentlessincreasesinthedebt-to-GDPratiointhebasecasescenario,arelativelylargeinitialincreaseintheprimarybudgetbalanceisneededtobenddownthedebtratiocurve.Inthisscenario,programexpendituresdeclinefrom37percentofGDPin2025to31.25percentin2030.(Thisisaverylarge,andperhapsunrealistic,fiscaladjust-mentoverarelativelyshorttime.)Asaresult,theprimarybudgetbalanceswitchesfromadeficitoftwopercentofGDPtoaprimarysurplusin2030of3.75percentofGDP.Followingthisperiodofexpenditurerestraint,theprogramexpenditure-to-GDPratiograduallyincreasestoitslong-runvalueof35.71percent,whichisconsistentwithmaintainingthedebtratioat50percentofGDP.6Figure2showsthetimepathsofthedebt-to-GDPratio,theeco-nomicgrowthrateandrealinterestrate,theprimarybudgetsurplus,andtheratioofinterestpaymentstorevenuesfromadoptingthispublicexpenditurerestraintpolicy.Asindicatedinfigure2,thedebt-to-GDPratioisloweredto50percentwithin10yearsandmaintainedatthatlevelthereafter.Withthereductionindebt-financedexpenditures,theCan-adianeconomicgrowthrateincreasesbyalmostonepercentagepointin2031,beforereturningtoitslong-runvalueof1.8percent.Thedeclineinthedebt-to-GDPratioafter2028resultsinagradualdeclineintherealinterestrateongovernmentdebtfrom0.98percentto0.38percentwhenthedebtratiohits50percent.Withthedeclineintherealinterestrateongovernmentdebt,thedifferencebetweentherealinterestrateandtheeconomicgrowthrateapproaches-1.4percent,whichmeansthatthe50percentdebtratiocanbemaintainedwithanongoingprimarybudgetdeficitof-0.71percentofGDP.Thedeclinesininterestratesandinthedebt-to-GDPratiolowertheratioofinterestpaymentstorevenuefrom6.0percentto3.41percent.Itisworthrepeatingthatwhiletheparticularfiscalpolicyadoptedinthisscenariotoobtaina20-percentagepointreductioninthedebt-to-GDPratioisnottheonlyonethatcouldachievethatgoal,asharpinitialThiswouldreturntheprogramexpenditureratioclosetotheaveragefrom1990to2019.CalculationsbytheauthorsarebasedonStatisticsCanadaTable10-10-0015-01.10?/?AnEvaluationofThreeAlternativeFiscalAnchorsforCanadaFigure2:LoweringtheDebtRatioby20PercentagePointsin10Years2A:TrajectoryofNetDebt-to-GDPofFPTLSectorUsingtheTargetDebt-to-GDPFiscalAnchor,2025to20508070GDP6050of40Percent3020100
2B:RealInterestRateandEconomicGrowthinCanada,2025to2050,UsingTargetDebt-to-GDPFiscalAnchor3.02.5Percent2.01.5RealInterestRate1.0GrowthRate0.50.0PercentofGDP
2C:PrimaryBudgetBalanceofFPTLSectorUsingTargetDebt-to-GDPFiscalAnchor,2025to2050543210-1-2-3
2D:RatioofInterestPaymentstoRevenuesofFPTLSectorUsingTargetDebt-to-GDPFiscalAnchor,2025to205076543210Source:CalculationsbyAnEvaluationofThreeAlternativeFiscalAnchorsforCanada?/?11reductioninthepublicexpenditure-to-GDPratioisanecessaryfeatureofanyexpenditurerestraintprogram,giventheunsustainableincreaseinthedebt-to-GDPratiointhebasecasescenario.AthresholdratioofinterestpaymentstorevenuesAsafiscalanchoror“guardrail”forthefederalgovernment,DavidDodge(2020)hasproposedkeepingtheratioofinterestpaymentstorevenuesbelow10percent.Recallthatinourbasecasescenario,theinterestpay-mentratiofortheFPTLsectorwouldexceedthisceilingin2039,andthatitwouldcontinuetoincreaseafterthat.Inthissection,wesimulateapolicyofimplementingwhatwewillcalltheDodgeRule.7AnimportantpolicychoicethatneedstobemadetoimplementtheDodgeRuleistheinterestpayment-to-revenueratiothatwouldtriggerapolicyresponsetopreventtheratiofromexceedingthe10percentceiling.Inoursimulation,weassumethatwhentheratioofinterestpaymentstorevenuesreaches8.0percent,governmentsadoptmeasurestokeeptheratiofromexceedingthe10percentceilingrecommendedbyMr.Dodge.Anaturalandperhapstheonlypossiblepolicyresponsetotheprospectofbreachingtheceilingwouldbetoincreasethedenominatoroftheratio,i.e.,revenues,becausethenumerator,interestpayments,arelargelybeyondagovernment’scon-trolintheshorttomediumterm.TheDodgeRulethusimpliesthatthefis-calpolicyadjustmentstopreventtheinterestpaymentratiofromexceed-ingceilingwouldinvolvetaxincreases,ratherthanexpenditurerestraint.TheimplementationoftheDodgeRuleisbasedonasequenceofannualtaxrises,startingin2034,thatwouldraisethetax-to-GDPratiofrom30percentto33.6percentin2038.Thehighertaxrevenueswouldbesufficienttoreturntheinterestpaymentratiobackto8.0percentin2050.Figure3showstheimpactofthissequenceoftaxincreasesontheotherkeyfiscalandeconomicvariables.Notethatthedebt-to-GDPratioinitiallyincreasesandapproaches90percentbecausethefiscalpolicyadjustmentisdelayeduntiltheinterestpaymentratiohits8.0percent.However,withthetaxincreasesstartingin2034,theprimarybudgetbalancerapidlyincreases,fromadeficitof2.4percentofGDPtoasurplusthatisclosetoonepercentofGDP,andthedebt-to-GDPratioisonadownwardtrajec-toryby2050.Thetaxrateincreaseshaveanadverseimpactontheeco-nomicgrowthrate,whichdeclinesfrom1.74in2034to0.10percentin2039beforerecoveringto1.41percentby2050.ThelargegapbetweentheOneconcernaboutusinganinterestpaymentratioasafiscalanchor,especiallyforaprovincialgovernmentsuchasAlberta,isthatyear-to-yearrevenuefluctuationscouldtemporarilypushtheratioabovea10percent12?/?AnEvaluationofThreeAlternativeFiscalAnchorsforCanadaFigure3:AdoptingtheDodgeRuleontheRatioofInterestPaymentstoRevenues3A:NetDebt-to-GDPofFPTLSectorUsi
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無(wú)特殊說(shuō)明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶(hù)所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁(yè)內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒(méi)有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒(méi)有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文庫(kù)網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶(hù)上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶(hù)上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶(hù)因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 健身驛站采購(gòu)合同范例
- 農(nóng)村瓦房售賣(mài)合同范例
- 高量子產(chǎn)率近紅外二區(qū)有機(jī)熒光體系的理論研究
- 基于深度學(xué)習(xí)的訪問(wèn)控制策略識(shí)別關(guān)鍵技術(shù)研究
- 藥卷錨桿施工方案
- 創(chuàng)傷理論視角下的托妮·莫里森《家》研究
- 產(chǎn)品訂購(gòu)運(yùn)輸合同范例
- 做生意合租合同范例
- 農(nóng)場(chǎng)店面轉(zhuǎn)讓合同范例
- 2011年比亞迪l3使用手冊(cè)
- 最新固體制空調(diào)凈化系統(tǒng)設(shè)計(jì)確認(rèn)方案
- 《汽車(chē)?yán)碚摗窂?fù)習(xí)提綱
- 利用勾股定理作圖計(jì)算(課堂PPT)
- 金合極思軟件快捷鍵
- 對(duì)大型火力發(fā)電廠生產(chǎn)準(zhǔn)備工作的幾點(diǎn)認(rèn)識(shí)
- 園林綠化監(jiān)理月報(bào)001
- 淺議如何當(dāng)好稅務(wù)分局長(zhǎng)
- 交通建設(shè)工程工程量清單計(jì)價(jià)規(guī)范(第1部分公路工程)-解析
- 山西曲沃(或經(jīng)洪洞縣大槐樹(shù))遷徙蘇北魯南曹氏宗系分支
- 干部管理訪談提綱
評(píng)論
0/150
提交評(píng)論