版權(quán)說明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請進(jìn)行舉報或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡介
FinanceandEconomicsDiscussionSeries
FederalReserveBoard,Washington,D.C.
ISSN1936-2854(Print)
ISSN2767-3898(Online)
MortgageDesign,RepaymentSchedules,andHouseholdBorrowing
ClaesB“ackman,PatrickMoran,PetervanSanten
2024-077
Pleasecitethispaperas:
B~ackman,Claes,PatrickMoran,andPetervanSanten(2024).“MortgageDesign,RepaymentSchedules,andHouseholdBorrowing,”FinanceandEconomicsDiscussionSeries2024-077.Washington:BoardofGovernorsoftheFederalReserveSystem,
/10.17016/FEDS.2024.077
.
NOTE:StafworkingpapersintheFinanceandEconomicsDiscussionSeries(FEDS)arepreliminarymaterialscirculatedtostimulatediscussionandcriticalcomment.TheanalysisandconclusionssetfortharethoseoftheauthorsanddonotindicateconcurrencebyothermembersoftheresearchstafortheBoardofGovernors.ReferencesinpublicationstotheFinanceandEconomicsDiscussionSeries(otherthanacknowledgement)shouldbeclearedwiththeauthor(s)toprotectthetentativecharacterofthesepapers.
MortgageDesign,RepaymentSchedules,andHouseholdBorrowing*
ClaesB¨ackmantPatrickMoran?PetervanSanten§
June4,2024
Abstract
Howdoesthedesignofdebtrepaymentschedulesaffecthouseholdborrowing?Toanswerthisquestion,weexploitaSwedishpolicyreformthateliminatedinterest-onlymortgagesforloan-to-valueratiosabove50%.Wedocumentsubstantialbunchingatthethreshold,leadingto5%lowerborrowing.Wealthyborrowersdrivetheresults,challengingcreditconstraintsastheprimaryexplanation.Wedevelopamodeltoevaluatethemechanismsdrivinghouseholdbehaviorandfindthatmuchoftheeffectcomesfromhouseholdsexperiencingongoingflowdisutilitytoamortizationpayments.Ourresultsindicatethatmortgagecontractswithlowinitialpaymentssubstantiallyincreasehouseholdborrowingandlifetimeinterestcosts.
JELClassification:G51,G21,E21,E6
Keywords:Mortgagedesign;Amortizationpayments;Macroprudentialpolicy;Bunching
*WethankRobAlessie,JohanAlmenberg,OlgaBalakina,VimalBalasubramaniam,EirikBrandsaas,TahaChoukhmane,TobinHanspal,StephanieJohnson(discussant),RagnarJuelsrud,KarinKinnerud,KavehMajlesi,ClemensSialm(discussant),JakobSogaard,LarsE.O.Svensson,NikodemSzumiloandseminarparticipantsattheECB,SverigesRiksbank,UniversityofGroningen,LundUniversity,NordicJuniorMacroSeminar,EFA,CentralBankofIrelandWorkshoponBorrowerFinances,theNFNYoungScholarsFinanceWebinarseries,IAAE,EEA-ESEM,theFederalReserveBoard,theFederalReserveBankofPhiladelphia,GoetheUniversity,theIMF,andASSA2024forhelpfulcomments.WegratefullyacknowledgeresearchsupportfromtheLeibnizInstituteforFinancialResearchSAFE.ClaesB¨ackmanwouldliketothankJanWallandersochTomHedeliusstiftelseforgenerousfinancialsupport.TheempiricalanalysisinthispaperwasdonewhenvanSantenworkedattheFinancialStabilityDepartmentofSverigesRiksbank.TheviewsexpressedinthispaperaresolelythoseoftheauthorsanddonotrepresenttheviewsoftheFederalReserveBoard,theFederalReserveSystem,orthe
Sve.teforFinancialResearchSAFE(
claes.backman@)
?FederalReserveBoard,CEBI,andIFS(
patrick.e.donnellymoran@)
§FacultyofEconomicsandBusiness,UniversityofGroningen(
p.c.van.santen@)
1
1Introduction
Oneofthemostimportantfeaturesofthemortgagecontractistherepaymentschedule.Mostmortgagesforcetheborrowertograduallyrepaythemortgageandbuildwealthintheformofhomeequity.Mandatorymortgagerepaymentrepresentsalargeshareofaggregatehouseholdsavings,similarinmagnitudetopensioncontributions(
Bernstein&Koudijs,
2023)
.Whilehistoricallyhouseholdshadlittlechoiceovertherepaymentschedule,financialinnovationduringrecentdecadescreatedawidevarietyofalternativemortgageproductsthatallowhouseholdstodelaymortgagerepayment(
Cocco,
2013
).Perhapsthemostfamousexampleistheinterest-onlymortgage,whichsurgedinpopularityinthemid-2000s,jumpingtoroughly25percentofmortgageoriginationsintheUnitedStatesduringtherun-upofmortgagedebtpriortothefinancialcrisis(
Amrominetal.,
2018)
.Financialregulatorsaroundtheworldcontinuetograpplewiththequestionofhowtoregulatethisimportantfeatureofthemortgagecontract.1
Despitetheimportantroleoftherepaymentschedule,wehavelittleevidenceonhowthisfeatureofthemortgagecontractaffectshouseholdborrowing.Thereareatleasttwocontrastingviews.Ononehand,interest-onlyloansrelaxcreditconstraints,helpingconstrainedhouseholdsborrowwhentheyexpectincomeorhousepricestogrow(
Piskorski&Tchistyi,
2010;
Cocco,
2013
).Ontheotherhand,manycommentatorshavesuggestedthatconsumersmaysufferfrombehavioralbiasesthatleadthemtoincreaseborrowingduetointerest-onlymortgages.Accordingtoonesuchtheory,bothconstrainedandunconstrainedconsumersmayprioritizealowmonthlypayment,whichishighlysalient,ratherthanminimizethenetpresentvalueoffutureinterestpayments(
Argyleetal.,
2020
).Whilewealreadyhaveclearevidenceontheroleofcreditconstraintsinmortgagelending,weknowlittleaboutthelattermechanism.
Tobetterunderstandhowtherepaymentscheduleaffectshouseholdborrowing,werequirequasi-experimentalvariationinrepaymentschedulesthataffectshouseholdswhoarefarfromtheircreditconstraints.Toachievethisgoal,weexploitapolicyreforminSwedenthatelimi-natedinterest-onlymortgagesforborrowerswithloan-to-value(LTV)ratiosabove50percent.Inresponsetothereform,wefindthatmanyhomebuyersmakelargerdownpayments,andexistingborrowersextractlessequity,leadingtobunchingjustbelowthe50percentLTVthreshold.Thereductioninborrowingisdrivenbyrelativelywealthyhouseholdswithsubstan-1Countrieshavetakendrasticallydifferentapproaches.WhiletheUSstronglydiscouragesinterest-onlymort-
gages,manyEuropeancountriescontinuetoallowthem.Incontrast,theUKhasrecentlybeguntoencouragebankstooffermortgageswithlongermaturitiestocounteractrisinginterestrates.
2
tialadditionalborrowingcapacity,thusrulingoutcreditconstraintsastheprimarydriverofourresults.Motivatedbytheempiricalevidence,wedevelopatheoreticalframeworktoclarifythemechanismsthatmayleadwealthy,unconstrainedhouseholdstoreduceborrowingtoavoidamortization.Wefindthatmuchoftheresponseisdrivennotbyfinancialconsiderationsbutratherbypsychiccosts.Morespecifically,wefindthathouseholdssufferongoingflowdisutilitytoamortizationpayments,whichleadsthemtochooseamortgagewithalowmonthlypayment,evenifitcomeswithhigherlifetimecosts.Identificationisdrivenbythefactthatmostofthebunchingisgeneratedwithoutamissingmass,whichalternativeversionsofthemodelwithoutflowdisutilityfailtogenerate.Ourresultsprovideevidencethathouseholdssufferfrom“NetPresentValue(NPV)neglect”inthespiritof
Shu
(2013)and
Argyleetal.
(2020)
.Asaresult,newmortgageproductswithdelayedrepaymentschedulesmaysubstantiallyincreasehouseholddebtandthelifetimecostsofinterestexpenditure.
Inourempiricalanalysis,weexploitanamortizationrequirementintroducedinSwedenin2016withtheintentofreducingmortgagedebt.Before2016,interest-onlymortgagesconsti-tutedthemajorityofmortgagecontractsinSweden.Theamortizationrequirementintroducedminimummandatorymortgagepaymentsbasedontheborrower’sloan-to-value(LTV)ratio.Morespecifically,forallmortgagesissuedafterJune2016,borrowerswithLTVratiosabove50percentarerequiredtorepayatleast1percentoftheoriginalloaneachyear,whileborrowerswithLTVratiosabove70percentarerequiredtorepayatleast2percent.MortgageswithLTVratiosbelow50percentarenotrequiredtobeamortized.Borrowerscanreduceamor-tizationpaymentsoncetheygetbelowtheLTVthresholds.Weestimatetheresponsetotherequirementusingadifference-in-bunchingestimator,usingpre-requirementyearstoformthecounterfactualLTVdistributionatorigination.WedocumentsignificantbunchingatbothLTVthresholds.NewborrowersreducetheirLTVratiosby5percentinresponsetoaonepercentagepointhigheraverageamortizationrate.
Whileitwouldbeeasytorationalizebunchingbybindingcreditconstraints,mosthouse-holdsatthepolicythresholdhavesubstantialadditionalborrowingcapacity,thuschallengingcreditconstraintsastheprimarydriverofourempiricalresults.First,borrowerscantakeoutsubstantiallylargermortgages,uptoamaximumLTVratioof85percent.Second,whileapayment-to-income(PTI)requirementmayinteractwiththeamortizationrequirement,mostbunchinghouseholdsstillhavesubstantialadditionalborrowingcapacity.Morespecifically,
3
whileroughly14percentofborrowersthatbunchatthe50percentLTVthresholdarecon-strainedbythePTIrequirement,theremaininghouseholdscouldborrowatleastanadditional$67,000(44percentofoursampleaverage)beforefacingbindingpaymentconstraints.Creditconstraintsarethusunabletoexplainourempiricalresults.
Weassessthevalidityofourempiricalapproachandtherobustnessofourresultsalongseveraldimensions.First,weconfirmthevalidityofourempiricalstrategyusingplacebotests,whichshowthatpreviousyearsindeedprovideavalidcounterfactualLTVdistribution.Second,estimatingthecounterfactualdistributionusingapolynomialapproach(
Kleven,
2016
)yieldslargerestimatesoftheimpactoftheamortizationrequirementonhouseholdborrowing.Third,wefindsimilarresultsforhouseholdsthatpurchaseapropertycomparedtothosewhorefinance,alleviatingconcernsabouthousingchoice.2Finally,weinvestigatevarioussupply-sidefactors(e.g.,mortgageapproval,collateralassessments,andrefinancingcosts)butfindthatnonecanexplainourresults.Forinstance,theinterestrateisflatovertheLTVthreshold,thusindicatingthatbunchingisnotdrivenbymortgagepricing.
Motivatedbytheempiricalevidence,wedevelopatheoreticalframeworktoclarifythemechanismsthatmayleadwealthyhouseholdstobunchbelowthepolicythresholdtoavoidamortizationpayments.Webeginwithatraditionallife-cyclemodelofconsumption,housing,andmortgagedecisionsinthespiritof
Campbell&Cocco
(2003)and
Cocco
(2005)
.Inthemodel,credit-constrainedhouseholdsborrowtopurchasehousingwhilefacedwithuninsurableidiosyncraticincomerisk.Householdsborrowusinglong-termmortgagecontractswithmanda-toryminimumpayments.Weallowfortwopolicyregimes:interest-only(IO)mortgagesandmandatoryamortizationpaymentsforhouseholdsabovethe50percentLTVthreshold.ThetwopolicyregimesbroadlyrepresenttheinstitutionalframeworkinSwedenbeforeandafterthe2016reform.
Whilethetraditionalmodeldescribedabovecouldeasilygeneratereducedborrowingforpoorhouseholdsfacingbindingcreditconstraints,itcannotgeneratebunchingbywealthyborrowersatthe50percentLTVthreshold.WeprovideintuitionforthelackofbunchingatthisthresholdbyinspectinghowexpecteddiscountedutilityvariesaccordingtotheLTVratio.Wefindthattheamortizationrequirementreducesexpectedutilityforallhouseholdsduetoreduced2Forrefinancers,thebanksetsthehomevalueexogenouslybasedontheirassessmentofthecollateralvalue.
TheseresultssupportourinterpretationthattheobserveddeclineinLTVratioscomesfromlowerloandemand(thenumeratorintheLTVratio)andnotfromchangesinhousingchoices(thedenominator).
4
flexibilitytosmoothconsumptionala
Cocco,
2013.
Thatsaid,theamortizationrequirementdoesnotcreateadiscontinuouschangeatthepolicythreshold,andthereforedoesnotresultinbunching.Thelackofbunchingbywealthyhouseholdsisrobusttoawidevarietyofalternativeassumptionsrelatedtopreferenceparameters,assetreturns,andrefinancingcosts.Indeed,evenwhenwegivehouseholdsaccesstoahigh-returnliquidasset,westilldonotfindwealthyhouseholdsbunchingatthe50percentLTVthreshold.
Ifthestandardmodeldoesnotgeneratebunchingforwealthy,unconstrainedhouseholds,whatpotentialextensionscanhelpthemodelreplicateourempiricalresults?
Kleven
(
2016
)ex-plainsthatfourmechanismsmaygeneratebunching:notchesorkinksinthebudgetconstraintornotchesorkinksinhouseholdpreferences.Asmentionedpreviously,wefindaverylimitedroleformechanismsoperatingthroughthebudgetconstraint.Wethereforeturnouratten-tiontowardshouseholdpreferences,extendingthemodelwithtwobroadclassesofbehavioralmechanismsthatmaygenerateeitheranotchorkinkinpreferences.Weadoptareduced-formapproachtobehavioralmodeling,remainingagnosticaboutthespecificbehavioralbiasesthatmaycreatethewedgeinhouseholdpreferences,following
Mullainathanetal.
(2012)
.
Thefirstmechanismisthathouseholdsmayexperienceaone-offdisutilitycostthatapplieswhenborrowersturnoffamortizationpayments.Thismechanismgeneratesanotchinhouseholdpreferences,astakingoutamortgagejustabovethe50percentLTVthresholdisdiscontinuouslyworsethantakingoutamortgagejustbelowthethreshold.Thisone-offdisutilitymayoccurifhouseholdsexperienceacosttomortgagerenegotiationwhencallingthebanktoturnoffamortizationpaymentsonceeligible.Wemodelthisasautilitycost,asmonetaryrefinancingcostsarelowinSweden.Thatsaid,variousbehavioralfactorscouldgenerateasimilarone-offcost,andourapproachneststhesepossibilities.Forinstance,ifhouseholdsareuncertainabouttheirabilitytoturnoffamortization,thiswouldcreateaone-offcost.Similarly,ifthepolicythresholdservesasatargetthatagentsstrivetoachieve,thenreferencedependencecouldalsogenerateanotchinhouseholdpreferences(
Kleven,
2016
).
Thesecondmechanismisthathouseholdsmaysufferongoingflowdisutilityfromamorti-zationpayments.Thismechanismgeneratesakinkinpreferences,astheeffectisstrongerforhouseholdsfurtherfromthe50percentLTVthreshold;assuch,householdsmustmakeamor-tizationpaymentsformoreperiods.Therearevariousrelatedmechanismsthatmaygenerateongoingflowdisutilityfromamortizationpayments.Forinstance,householdsmayperform
5
“monthlypaymenttargeting,”wheretheyfocusontargetingaspecificmonthlymortgagepay-mentratherthanminimizingthelifetimecostoftheloan,inthespiritof
Argyleetal.
(2020)
.Similarly,householdsmayviewamortizationpaymentsasacostratherthanaformofsaving,inthespiritof
Camanho&Fernandes
(2018)
.3Ineithercase,suchpreferencesimplythathouse-holdsdonotfullyconsiderthenetpresentvalue(NPV)offutureinterestcostswhenchoosingbetweenmortgagecontractswithalternativerepaymentschedules.Asaresult,householdsmaychoosecontractswithlowerinitialpaymentsandhigherlifetimecosts,evenwhentheycouldaffordtodootherwise.Werefertothisconceptas“NPVneglect”following
Shu
(2013)
.
Todisentangletherelativecontributionofthesetwoverydifferentmechanisms,weexploitthattheone-offdisutilitycostgeneratesanotchinhouseholdpreferenceswhileongoingflowdisutilitygeneratesakink.Thisdistinctionisusefulforidentification,asnotchesgeneratebunchingduetoadominatedregionwithmissingmassdirectlyabovethethreshold,whileincontrast,kinksaltertheincentivesforallhouseholdsabovethethreshold,thusgeneratingbunchingwithoutamissingmass.Inthedata,wefindthatlessthan15percentofbunchingisexplainedbymissingmassdirectlyabovethethreshold.ThelackofmissingmassisdifficulttorationalizewithoptimizingfrictionssinceborrowerscanchoosetheLTVvaluedirectlyandsincetheconsequencesofchoosingahigherLTVarehighlysalient.Weconcludethatwhilebothmechanismsplayarole,mostoftheresponseisdrivenbyhouseholdssufferingongoingflowdisutilitytoamortization,consistentwiththetheoryof“NPVneglect.”
Ourresultshaveimportantimplicationsforunderstandingthelinkbetweenfinancialinno-vationandhouseholdborrowing.InaworldwithNPVneglect,newmortgageproductswithinterest-onlypayments(orlongermaturities)havelargeaggregateeffectsonhouseholddebt.Moreover,suchproductssubstantiallyincreaselifetimeinterestexpenses.Todemonstrate,weuseourmodeltostudyoneofthekeyaspectsoffinancialinnovationinUSmortgagemarketsduringthelate1990sandearly2000s:thetransitionfromtraditional30-yearmortgagestoalternativemortgageproductswithlessstringentrepaymentschedules.Webeginwithanecon-omywherehouseholdsonlyhaveaccessto30-yearamortizingmortgages,thensuddenlyallowhouseholdstoborrowusingIOmortgages.IntroducingIOmortgagesincreasesmortgagedebtbyabout33percentinourcalibratedmodel.Thestructuralmodelallowsustodecomposethedifferentchannelsdrivingtheincreaseinborrowing.Wefindthatroughlytwo-thirdsofthe
3InSwedishsurveyevidence,38percentofrespondentsstatethatamortizationpaymentsareacost,44percentstatethatamortizationpaymentsareaformofsavings,and18percentdonotknow(
SBAB,
2018)
.
6
increasecomesfrom“NPVneglect,”whiletheremainingone-thirdcomesfromrelaxedcreditconstraints(inthespiritof
Cocco,
2013
).Thepolicychangehasasimilareffectoninterestexpenditures,whichalsoincreaseby33percentoverthelife-cycle.Inshort,wefindthat“NPVneglect”amplifiestheeffectsoffinancialinnovationonhouseholdborrowing.Thedegreeofamplificationisheightenedbythefactthatwefindakinkratherthananotchinhouseholdpreferences.Hadhouseholds’observedbehaviorbeendrivenbyanotch,therewouldhavebeenonlyalocaleffectonhouseholdborrowingand,thus,asmalleramplificationrelativetothetraditionalmodel.
Takingstock,ourfindingshaveimportantimplicationsforunderstandinghouseholdprefer-encesfordebtrepayment.Andwhilewefocusonthemortgagemarket,manyofourresultsextendtootherformsofconsumerborrowing,wherethereisasimilardebateabouthowhouse-holdsrespondtonewfinancialproductswithlongermaturitiesorlowerinitialpayments.Un-derstandingthesepreferencesiscrucialforbothconsumerprotectionagenciesconcernedaboutthewelfareeffectsofnewfinancialproducts,aswellasmacroprudentialregulatorsconcernedaboutaggregatedebtlevels.
RelatedLiterature.Weseethreemaincontributionsofthispaper.First,weprovidenovelevidencethatrepaymentschedulesaffectborrowingdecisions,evenforunconstrainedborrowers,whichhelpsimproveourunderstandingofhouseholdpreferencesfordebtrepayment.Weviewourresultsascomplementaryto
Argyleetal.
(2020),whofindthatconsumersperform“monthly
paymenttargeting”whenchoosingbetweenautoloans,eveninsubsamplesofunconstrainedborrowers.Inasimilarspirit,
Shu
(2013)providessurveyevidenceof“NPVneglect,”the
tendencyofborrowerstotargetinitialpaymentsizeinsteadofminimizingthenetpresentvalueoffutureinterestcosts.Furthersurveyevidenceby
Camanho&Fernandes
(
2018
)showsthatmanyindividualsdecidewhethertopurchasehousingbasedonthedifferencebetweenmonthlyrentalpaymentsandmonthlymortgagepayments,evenwhenthelatterincludesamortizationpayments.Relativetotheexistingliterature,wearethefirsttoevaluatethepresenceof“NPVneglect”inobservedmortgagedecisions,aswellasthefirsttoevaluatethistheoryusingquasi-experimentalevidence.
Second,wecontributetothegrowingliteratureonmortgagedesign,whichhasrecentlyshownincreasinginterestinmortgagerepaymentschedules.4
Bernstein&Koudijs
(2023)showthat
4Seealsoseminalcontributionsfrom
Cocco
(2013)and
Piskorski&Tchistyi
(2010)
.Recentpapersonthetopicalsoinclude
Vihri¨al¨a
(2023)and
Ferrari&Loseto
(2023)
.
7
amortizationpaymentscontributesubstantiallytohouseholdwealthaccumulation.
Campbell
etal.
(2020)studyamodelwhereanoptiontoloweramortizationpaymentsinarecession
helpstostabilizeconsumption.
Gurenetal.
(2021)studyanequilibriummodelwherecounter
-cyclicalpaymentreductionsreducedefaultandstimulatehousingdemand.
Attanasioetal.
(2021)evaluatetheroleofamortizationpaymentsasasavingscommitmentdevice
.
Ganong
&Noel
(2020)findthatextendingmortgagematurityhasalargeimpactondefaultrates
.
Amrominetal.
(2018)showthatinterest-onlymortgageswereusedbyprimeborrowersinthe
UShousingboom.
Garmaise
(2013)showsthatincreasedflexibilityinmortgagecontractsled
tohigherborrowing.Wealsonotethatamortizationpaymentsrepresentade-factoconstraintonsavingsandborrowingforpayment-constrainedborrowers.Amortizationpaymentshaverecentlybeenincludedinseveraltheoreticalmodelsthatincorporaterealisticfeaturesofthemortgagecontract(
Greenwald,
2017;
Kaplanetal.,
2020;
Boaretal.,
2022
),buttheinteractionwithcreditconstraintshasreceivedlessattention.Withinthisliterature,wearethefirsttoconsiderthepossibilitythathouseholdsmaysufferfrombehavioralbiaseswhenchoosingbetweenmortgagecontractswithalternativerepaymentschedules.
Third,ourresultsarerelevantforunderstandingtheroleoffinancialinnovationincontribut-ingtotheaccumulationofmortgagedebtpriortothe2008financialcrisis.Loweramortizationpaymentsinthefirstyearsafteroriginationwereacommonfeatureofinterest-onlymortgages,optionARMs,andballoonmortgagesintherun-uptotheGreatRecessionintheUnitedStates
(Amrominetal.,
2018;
Barlevy&Fisher,
2020;
Justinianoetal.,
2021)
.Similaroccurredinothercountries:Australia,Denmark,Finland,Greece,Korea,andPortugalallintroducedinterest-onlymortgagesbetween1995and2005(
Scanlonetal.,
2008
).Ourresultssuggestthattheincreasedavailabilityandsubsequentdisappearanceofnon-traditionalmortgageswithloweramortizationpaymentscanexplainlargemovementsinhouseholddebtintheUnitedStates.Lookingforward,policymakersshouldbeawarethatdebtrepaymentschedulescouldhavelargeconsequencesforcreditgrowth.Ourresults,therefore,alsocontributetothegrowingliteratureontheeffectofmacroprudentialpolicies(e.g.
Ceruttietal.,
2017;
Laufer&Tzur-Ilan,
2019;
Peydr′oetal.,
2020;
DeFuscoetal.,
2020
).
Methodologically,thepresentpaperbuildsuponagrowingliteraturethatusesbunchingtounderstandpreferences.Theuseofbunchingtoidentifypreferenceshasreceivedattentioninreviewarticlesby
Kleven
(2016)and
DellaVigna
(2018)
.Prominentexamplesinhousehold
8
financeinclude
Andersenetal.
(2022)whostudyreferencedependenceinhousingmarkets,
Choukhmane
(2021)whostudiesopt-outcostsinretirementdecisions,
Collieretal.
(2021)
whostudycollateralaversioninlendingmarkets,and
Bestetal.
(2020)whoestimatethe
intertemporalelasticityofsubstitutionusingmortgagedecisions.Otherprominentexamplesinclude
Laceteraetal.
(2012)and
Strulov-Shlain
(2023)whostudyleft-digitbiasinpricing
.Tothebestofourknowledge,wearethefirsttousebunchingtostudy“NPVneglect.”
SeveralstudiesexaminetheeffectoftheSwedishamortizationrequirement.
Andersson&
Aranki
(2017)useadifference-in-differencestrategytoshowthattheamortizationrequirement
reducedhouseholdborrowing.
Andersson&Aranki
(2019)analyzetheadditionalamortization
requirementintroducedin2018thatmandatedthatmortgageswithadebt-to-incomeratioabove4.5hadtobeamortizedbyanadditionalpercentagepoint.Theauthorsshowthathouseholdsareborrowing,onaverage,8.5percentlessthantheyotherwisewouldhavedoneandthattheyarealsobuyinglessexpensivehomes.
Wilhelmsson
(2022)findsthattheamortization
requirementledtoa7percentreductioninhouseprices.
Thepaperisorganizedasfollows.Section
2
describestheSwedishmortgagemarketandtheamortizationrequirement.Section
3
presentsthedataanddiscussestheempiricalstrategy.Section
4
providesthemainempiricalresults.Section
5
developsatheoreticalframeworktounderstandhouseholds’responsetotheamortizationrequirement.Section
6
summarizesanddiscussespotentialextensions.
2TheAmortizationRequirement
TheSwedishhousingandcreditmarketsexperiencedrapidgrowthintheearly2010s.Housepricesincreasedby31percentbetween2011and2015,andcreditgrowthincreasedfrom5percentin2012toover8percentin2015.Concernedwithfinancialandmacroeconomicsta-bility,theSwedishFinancialSupervisoryAuthority(Finansinspektionen,orFSA)announcedthattheywouldproposenewregulationinNovember2014–theamortizationrequirement–intendingtoreducedebtlevelsovertime.Thepurposewastolimitmacroeconomicrisksposedbyhighhouseholddebtlevels.TheFSAconsideredhouseholdswithhigherLTVratiosahigherrisk;consequently,regulationtargetedthisgroup.TherequirementcameontopofthecurrentrecommendationbytheSwedishBankersAssociation(SBA),whichrecommendedthatborrow-ersamortizeiftheirLTVvaluesexceeded70percent.Theamortizationrequirementwasfinally
9
Amortizationrate
(%)
2.0
1.5
1.0
2016-2018
Requirement
2014-2015
0.5
Recommendation
2011-2013
0.0
0102030405060708
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無特殊說明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁內(nèi)容里面會有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文庫網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲空間,僅對用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- Syringaresinol-diglucoside-Standard-生命科學(xué)試劑-MCE
- Sulfaethoxypyridazine-Standard-生命科學(xué)試劑-MCE
- 七年級生物下冊第六章第四節(jié)激素調(diào)節(jié)課時練新版新人教版
- 2025屆新教材高考地理一輪復(fù)習(xí)第十二單元區(qū)域聯(lián)系與區(qū)域發(fā)展第二節(jié)資源跨區(qū)域調(diào)配對區(qū)域發(fā)展的影響-以我國南水北調(diào)為例學(xué)案魯教版
- 2024年二元酸二甲酯項(xiàng)目合作計劃書
- 玉溪師范學(xué)院《教師職業(yè)道德與教育政策法規(guī)》2023-2024學(xué)年第一學(xué)期期末試卷
- 玉溪師范學(xué)院《國際貨運(yùn)與保險》2022-2023學(xué)年第一學(xué)期期末試卷
- 玉溪師范學(xué)院《程序設(shè)計》2023-2024學(xué)年期末試卷
- 玉溪師范學(xué)院《教育社會學(xué)》2022-2023學(xué)年第一學(xué)期期末試卷
- 2024年喹吖啶酮類合作協(xié)議書
- 通信線路工程驗(yàn)收規(guī)范-原文件
- 二次供水工程技術(shù)規(guī)程(CJJ140—2010 )
- 腦梗死標(biāo)準(zhǔn)病歷、病程記錄、出院記錄模板
- 鋼鐵動力廠 氮?dú)夤芫€不停車帶壓開孔工程施工方案
- Kolcaba的舒適狀況量表
- ISO13485-2016跟ISO9001-2015條款對應(yīng)關(guān)系
- ??低曇曨l車位誘導(dǎo)與反向?qū)ぼ囅到y(tǒng)解決方案
- 個案護(hù)理報告范文參考
- 康復(fù)護(hù)理學(xué)第五章-常用康復(fù)治療技術(shù)二1
- 小學(xué)生日常衛(wèi)生小常識(課堂PPT)
- 幼兒園大班《風(fēng)箏飛上天》教案
評論
0/150
提交評論