版權(quán)說(shuō)明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請(qǐng)進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡(jiǎn)介
Efficiency,Equity,andCost-
RecoveryTrade-OffsinMunicipalWaterPricing
CaseyJ.Wichman
WorkingPaper24-18
October2024
AbouttheAuthor
CaseyWichmanisanassociateprofessorintheSchoolofEconomicsattheGeorgiaInstituteofTechnologyandauniversityfellowatResourcesfortheFuture.Heisanappliedmicroeconomistworkingonissuesattheintersectionofenvironmentaland
publiceconomics.Hisresearchfocusesonhowpeopleinteractwiththenaturalandbuiltenvironment,andwhatthatbehaviorrevealsaboutthevalueofenvironmental
amenities.Wichman’sresearchspanswaterandenergydemandmanagement,climatechangeimpactsandpolicy,urbantransportation,publicgoodsprovision,andoutdoorrecreation.
Acknowledgements
IthankDylanBrewer,NathanChan,TeevratGarg,LudovicaGazze,BenGilbert,
JoshGraffZivin,ArikLevinson,SheilaOlmstead,IvanRudik,BlakeShaffer,Steven
Smith,ChrisTimmins,WillWheeler,DerekWietelman,andconferenceandseminar
participantsattheTriangleResourceandEnvironmentalEconomicsseminar,ColoradoSchoolofMines,UniversityofAlabama,UniversityofCalgary,UCSanDiego,
UniversityofHouston,UniversityofWyoming,thePropertyandEnvironmentResearchCenter
(PERC),theYoungScholarsSymposiumonNaturalResourceGovernanceatIndianaUniversity,aswellasthe2023ASSA,AERE,andSEAmeetingsforhelpfulfeedback.ThisresearchwaspartiallysupportedbyagrantfromtheGeorgiaTechStrategicPlanAdvisoryGroupandtheLoneMountainFellowshipatPERC.TurnerStevensprovidedexceptionalresearchassistance.
ResourcesfortheFuturei
AboutRFF
ResourcesfortheFuture(RFF)isanindependent,nonprofitresearchinstitutionin
Washington,DC.Itsmissionistoimproveenvironmental,energy,andnaturalresourcedecisionsthroughimpartialeconomicresearchandpolicyengagement.RFFis
committedtobeingthemostwidelytrustedsourceofresearchinsightsandpolicysolutionsleadingtoahealthyenvironmentandathrivingeconomy.
Workingpapersareresearchmaterialscirculatedbytheirauthorsforpurposesof
informationanddiscussion.Theyhavenotnecessarilyundergoneformalpeerreview.TheviewsexpressedherearethoseoftheindividualauthorsandmaydifferfromthoseofotherRFFexperts,itsofficers,oritsdirectors.
SharingOurWork
OurworkisavailableforsharingandadaptationunderanAttribution-
NonCommercial-NoDerivatives4.0International(CCBY-NC-ND4.0)license.Youcancopyandredistributeourmaterialinanymediumorformat;youmustgive
appropriatecredit,providealinktothelicense,andindicateifchangesweremade,andyoumaynotapplyadditionalrestrictions.Youmaydosoinanyreasonable
manner,butnotinanywaythatsuggeststhelicensorendorsesyouoryouruse.Youmaynotusethematerialforcommercialpurposes.Ifyouremix,transform,orbuilduponthematerial,youmaynotdistributethemodifiedmaterial.Formoreinformation,visit
/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
.
Efficiency,Equity,andCost-RecoveryTrade-OffsinMunicipalWaterPricing
Efficiency,Equity,andCost-RecoveryTrade-Offs
inMunicipalWaterPricing*
CaseyJ.Wichman?October11,2024
Abstract
Municipalwaterutilitieschooseratestorecovercosts,encourageconservation,andreduceburdensonlow-incomecustomers,whichmaydeviatefromoptimaltwo-parttariffs.Theorysuggeststhatpricesshouldequalmarginalcostwithfixedcostsrecoveredviafixedfeesoralternativetaxrevenues.Usingratestructureandmunicipalfinancedataformorethan700utilities,Ishowthatpricesarediscountedseverelyforlowlevelsofconsumptionwithinnonlinearratestructures,leadingtosuboptimalusageandbudgetdeficits,particularlyinpoorerandsmallercommunities.Marginal-costpricingcorrectsallocativeinefficiencies,andequityandcost-recoverygoalscanbeachievedthroughmoreprogressiveapproachestofixedcosts,whicharebothhighlyregressiveandalargeshareoftotalcosts.
KeyWords:waterpricing;utilitymanagement;naturalmonopolies;two-parttariffs;nonlin-earpricing;affordability;municipalfinance.
JELcodes:D12,H23,L95,Q25
*IthankDylanBrewer,NathanChan,TeevratGarg,LudovicaGazze,BenGilbert,JoshGraffZivin,ArikLevinson,SheilaOlmstead,IvanRudik,BlakeShaffer,StevenSmith,ChrisTimmins,WillWheeler,DerekWietelman,andcon-ferenceandseminarparticipantsattheTriangleResourceandEnvironmentalEconomicsseminar,ColoradoSchoolofMines,UniversityofAlabama,UniversityofCalgary,UCSanDiego,UniversityofHouston,UniversityofWyoming,thePropertyandEnvironmentResearchCenter(PERC),theYoungScholarsSymposiumonNaturalResourceGover-nanceatIndianaUniversity,aswellasthe2023ASSA,AERE,andSEAmeetingsforhelpfulfeedback.ThisresearchwaspartiallysupportedbyagrantfromtheGeorgiaTechStrategicPlanAdvisoryGroupandtheLoneMountainFellowshipatPERC.TurnerStevensprovidedexceptionalresearchassistance.
?Wichman:AssociateProfessor,SchoolofEconomics,GeorgiaInstituteofTechnology,221BobbyDoddWay,Atlanta,GA30332.Email:
wichman@;UniversityFellow,ResourcesfortheFuture
.
1
1Introduction
Municipalwaterandwastewaterutilitiesaretaskedwiththeoperationofcriticalinfrastructureforthewell-beingoftheirresidents:deliveringclean,safe,andreliabledrinkingwaterandre-turningittonaturalwaterbodieswithoutharmingtheenvironment.Duetopoliticalpressure,concernsaboutaffordability,andtheUnitedNations’declarationthataccesstowaterisahu-
manright(UNGeneralAssembly,
2010),waterpricestypicallydonotreflectthetruecostof
service(Hanemann,
1997;
Timmins,
2002b;
Olmstead,
2010)
.Failuretorecovercostscanprevent
utilitiesfrominvestingininfrastructureandmaintainingservicequality(McRae,
2015)
.Evenindevelopedcountries,poorfiscalmanagementcanresultincatastrophicconsequences,suchas
recentservicefailuresinJackson,MS,1
orFlint,MI(Christensenetal.,
2023)
.Efficiencysuggeststhatpricesshouldequallong-runmarginalcostsofprovision,bututilities—–largelyoperatedbyfinanciallyandpoliticallyconstrainedmunicipalgovernments—–needtobalanceequityconsid-erationswithrevenueneedsandclearmarketsignals
.2
Inbalancingthesegoals,utilitiesoften
adoptnonlinearratestructuresthatdiscountmarginalpricesforlowlevelsofconsumption(Olm-
steadetal.,
2007;
Szabo,
2015;
WangandWolak,
2022;
AllaireandDinar,
2022),althoughthese
pricingdecisionsmaygenerateallocativeinefficiencies(Borenstein,
2012,
2016;
Borensteinand
Davis,
2012),requiresubsidizationfromalternativemunicipalrevenuesources(Timmins,
2002a;
Renzetti,
1999),andineffectivelyredistributeincome(LevinsonandSilva,
2022;
Wietelmanetal.,
2024)
.
Ievaluatetheextenttowhichprevailingwaterpricesdeviatefromeconomicallyoptimalrates,whatdrivesthoseinefficiencies,andwhatimplicationsmispricedwaterserviceshaveonsocialwelfareandutilityrevenue.Ifirstrevisitclassictheoryontwo-partpricinginthespiritof
Coase
(1946),butIrefocusthisframeworkoncontemporaryissuesinmunicipalwaterandwastewater
pricing.Theframeworkdemonstratesthecanonicalefficiencyresultthatpriceshouldequalmarginalcost.However,unlikerecentresearchconcerningincreasing-blockrate(IBR)pricing
forprivate,regulatedelectricutilities(LevinsonandSilva,
2022),municipalmanagerscanrelax
theutility’sbudgetconstraintviaintragovernmentaltransfers.Inpractice,utilitiesoftenrundeficits(subsidizingwaterservicefromgeneralfundrevenue)orsurpluses(fundingotherlocalpublicgoodsthroughwaterrates),soassumingthatthezero-profitconditionholdsisrestrictive.Relaxingthisconstraintallowsmunicipalitiestodrawfromalternativesourcesofrevenuetorecoverfixedcosts.Fixedhouseholdservicefeesforwaterandwastewater—often$250–350peryearorapproximately40–50percentofwaterexpenditures—operateaslump-sumtaxesonhouseholds,whichislikelythemostregressiveformofrevenueraisedbylocalgovernments
.3
1See,forexample,
/news/2023/06/28/timeline-jackson-mississippi-water-problems.
(accessedJune19,2024).
2Approximately150,000USwatersystemsintheUnitedStatesprovidewaterandwastewaterservicesto90
percentoftheUSpopulation;thevastmajorityofthesearepubliclyowned(/dwreginfo/
information-about-public-water-systems)
.
3Fixedaccessfeesdonotvarybyincome.Propertyandsalestaxes,thetwomostlikelysourcesofmunicipalrevenue,arealsoregressive,butconsumptionandpropertyvaluestendtoincrease,albeitlessthanproportionally,withincome.
2
Waterutilitiesthatcareaboutequitycansetthevolumetricrateequaltomarginalcostand,todealwithredistributionandrecoupfixedcosts,theycansetanindividualizedfixedmonthlyservicefeethattargetsdifferencesinincome(e.g.,bysettingservicefeesproportionaltopropertyvalues)orrelyonlessregressivesourcesofmunicipalrevenue.
Empirically,Iexplorewhetherwaterpricesdeviatefromoptimaltwo-parttariffsusingmorethanadecadeofannualdataonutilityratestructuresandmunicipalfinanceinformationformorethan700utilitiesintheSoutheasternUnitedStates
.4
Iprovideevidencethatutilitiesfailtobalancetheirbudgetexactlyand,onaverage,pricewaterbelowaveragecost.Usingvariationinoperatingexpendituresovertimeandacrossutilitiesinsimilarhydrologicregions,Iestimatemarginalcostsforwaterandwastewaterservicesandusetheseestimatestoevaluatehowmuchutilitiesdiscountormarkupwaterrates,accountingfornonlinearitiesintheratestructure.ThepredominantratestructuresareIBRsanduniformratesthatincludeanallocationofwateratzeromarginalprice(“uniform+free”),bothofwhichdiscountvolumetricpricesseverelyforlowlevelsofuse,accountingfornearlyhalfoftheconsumptiondistribution.ThemedianpricediscountforutilitieswithIBRsinthefirsttier(0–3kgal/month)isapproximately34percent,withpricesinhighertiersmarkedupby5–27percentabovemarginalcost.Themedianutilitythatprovidesanallocationoffreewaterinitsuniformratestructurediscountspricesby65percentinthefirsttier,withapproximatelymarginal-costpricinginhighertiers.Utilitieswithpurelyuniformratespricewater,onaverage,closetomarginalcost.
Whydoutilitiessubsidizeasubstantialportionofconsumptionthroughdiscountedmarginalprices?Commonexplanationsarethatthemanagersareinfluencedbypoliticalpressuretokeep
priceslow(Timmins,
2002b)andprovidebasicwaterserviceatlowcostforlow-incomecus
-
tomers(Szabo,
2015),despitemaintainingalump-sumtransferinstrumentonthebillthatcan
addressequityand/oraffordabilityconcernsmoredirectlyandmoreeffectively.Iexplorethefactorsassociatedwithinefficientpricingbycomparingwaterratesandmarkupsacrossutili-tiesinsimilarhydrologicregions.Severalresultsemerge.First,volumetricsubsidiesaremuchmorecommoninsmallerutilities,whichhavehigheraveragecostsofservice;theirinabilitytocapitalizeoneconomiesofscalereducesthelikelihoodofpassingthefullcoststhroughtocus-tomers.Second,volumetricpricesarelowerandmoreheavilydiscountedforutilitieswithlargerlow-incomepopulations,whichisnotablebecauseitrevealsanefficiency–equitytrade-off:theseutilitiesaremorelikelytosubsidizevolumetricpricesratherthanalterthefixedservicefeeorcoverfixedcostsviamunicipalrevenue.Third,waterratesandmarkupsarelargerforcommu-nitieswithnewerhomes,morerenters,andahigherproportionofnon-Whiteresidents.Fourth,greaterhistoricaldroughtintensityincreasesvolumetricpricesbutnotmarkups,indicatingthatscarcityispotentiallypricedintowaterratesviahighermarginalcosts.Furthermore,Ishowthat
4MysampleincludesthevastmajorityofutilitiesinGeorgiaandNorthCarolina,whicharetheeighthandninthmostpopulousstates,respectively.Combined,theirpopulation(~21M)wouldrepresentthefourthlargeststate,afterCalifornia(~39M),Texas(~31M),andFlorida(~23M),comprising6–7percentoftheUSpopulation.Intermsofeconomicoutput,NorthCarolina’sGDPin2023was$626B,andGeorgia’swas$661;combined,theywouldbecomparabletoIndonesia,theNetherlands,Turkey,andSaudiArabiainworldeconomicoutput.
3
thesepricingdecisionsareconsequentialforutilityoperations:decreasesinfixedfeesandinvolumetricpricesinthelowesttierincreasethelikelihoodthatautilityfailstocoveritscosts.
Next,Iestimaterevenueelasticities,whichindirectlyrevealspriceelasticitiesofdemand,leveragingyear-to-yearvariationintheutility-levelpaneldataonrevenuesandratechanges.Iadoptaninstrumental-variable(IV)strategytoaccountfornonlinearratestructuresandpo-tentiallyendogenousratechangesusingratestructurecharacteristicsfromneighboringutilities.Theestimatedrevenueelasticitiessuggestthatforevery10percentincreaseinvolumetricprices,revenuesincreasebyapproximately4–5percent,whichimpliespriceelasticityestimatesof?0.5to?0.6.Usingtheseelasticitiesandtheestimatedmarginalcosts,Isimulaterevenueandsocialwelfareimplicationsofadoptingefficientpricing.Manyutilitiescanincreaserevenuebypricingatmarginalcost,whichislargelyadirectsurplustransferfromconsumers.Inmostcases,thatsurplusdeclinesduetoremovaloftheinframarginalvolumetricsubsidyimplicitinthenonlinearratestructures.Whetherconsumptionincreasesordecreasesdependsonthepresumedmodelofpriceperceptionandthewedgebetweenpricesandmarginalcosts.Marginalpricesaregenerallycloseto,orslightlylargerthan,marginalcost,whichimpliesthatconsumptionincreasesslightly
ifconsumersrespondtomarginalprice(Olmsteadetal.,
2007;
NatarajandHanemann,
2011)
.Forutilitieswithnonlinearratestructures,averagevolumetricpricestendtofallbelowmarginalcostsduetoinframarginaldiscounts,soconsumptiondecreasesifconsumersrespondtoaver-
ageprice(Ito,
2014;
Wichman,
2014;
BrentandWard,
2019;
Shaffer,
2020)
.Regardlessofpriceperception,nonlinearratesgenerateallocativeinefficiencies,whicharealleviatedbymarginal-costpricing.Forthemedianutility,marginal-costpricingeliminatesdeadweightlossandraisesrevenue,whichalmostoffsetsconsumersurpluslosses.Althoughthisispurelyanefficiencyresult,therevenuegainscanbeusedtoadvancedistributionalgoals,byeitheradoptinglower(orprogressive)fixedfeesorleveragingalternative,lessregressivesourcesofmunicipalrevenuetorecoverfixedcosts.
Thispapermakesseveralcontributionstoourunderstandingofinefficienciesinutilitypric-ing.Igeneratenewinsightsonnaturalmonopolypricingthatbalancesequity–efficiencytrade-offsanddocumentwidespreadpricinginefficienciesinthemunicipalwatersector.Thispaperaddstoalong-standinglineofinquiryonoptimalpricingformunicipalutilityservices,someofwhichisfocusedontheredistributionalimplicationsofnonlinearrates(e.g.,
Borenstein,
2012;
BorensteinandDavis,
2012;
LevinsonandSilva,
2022;
BorensteinandBushnell,
2022)
.Mostre-searchonwaterpricingadoptsmodelingframeworksfromenergypricing,butwaterutilitiesaredistinctfromenergyutilitiesinseveralimportantways.First,theytypicallyjointlymanageproduction,distribution,andtreatment,whichisatypicalofenergyutilities.Relatedly,becauseoftheprohibitivecostsofmovingwaterlongdistances,waterutilitiesaresmallerandmanagedmuchmorelocally.Bothofthesefactorslimittheirabilitytobenefitfromscaleeconomies
.5
Asaresult,percapitafixedcostsofwaterservice(and,hence,fixedcharges)arerelativelylarge
5Toemphasizethispoint,Georgiahas52municipallyownedelectricutilities,41electricmembershipcorporations,andoneinvestor-ownedutilitythatoperatesin155ofits159counties(source:
/utilities/
electric/)
.Bycontrast,Ianalyze382municipalwaterutilitiesinGeorgiathatserve,onaverage,5,000customers.
4
anddeservemoreexplicitattentioninwaterpricing.Second,waterutilitiesareoverwhelminglyoperatedbymunicipalgovernments,soratesareregulatedindirectlybyvotersandtypicallynotbyautilitycommission
.6
Thisstructureallowsutilitiestotapintoalternativesourcesofmunicipalrevenue,whicharelessregressivethanafixedlump-sumtaxtorecoverfixedcosts.Third,waterserviceprovidesmanylocalpublicgoods,suchaswaterprovisionforfireprotectionandstormwaterinfrastructureforfloodprotection,thatarefundedthroughutilitybillsandcan
rationalizemunicipalsubsidies(Beecher,
2020)
.
Thispaperalsocontributestoourunderstandingofnonlinearpricingforutilityservices.SeveralstudiesexploretheeffectsofIBRsforelectricity,naturalgas,andwateruseatthehouse-holdlevel(e.g.,
ReissandWhite,
2005;
Olmsteadetal.,
2007;
NatarajandHanemann,
2011;
Ito,
2014;
Wichman,
2014;
Szabo,
2015),butlittleworkhasfocusedonutility-wideconsequences,es
-peciallyforwaterandwastewaterservices
.7
Nonlinearratesarebeingincreasinglyadoptedforwater,largelyunderthebannerofachievingconservationandreducingburdensonlow-incomecustomers.ThisresearchhaslargelyfocusedonIBRs,butIadditionallyhighlightacommonhiddeninefficiencyinutilitypricingdecisions:manyutilitiespossessratestructuresthatembedanallocationoffreeconsumption(onaverage,1–3kgal/monthpercustomer).Thesenonlinearvolumetricratestructuresdonotreflectcosts,oftenrequiresubsidizationfromotherrevenuesources,andcanleadtosuboptimalconsumptionbydrivingawedgebetween(infra-)marginalpricesandmarginalcosts.Ishowthatuniform,marginal-costpricingcaneliminateallocativeinefficienciesandincreaserevenuebyremovingvolumetricsubsidies,whichcouldbeused,inprinciple,tolowerfixedfeesoroffsetthemwithlessregressivesourcesofmunicipalrevenue.
Last,comparativeanalysesofwaterutilitiesarerarebecausenocentralizedrepositoryofdatalinkswaterratestructureswithmunicipalrevenueandcostinformationforthesameutilitiesovertime.Mostresearchonmunicipalwaterpricingevaluatesconsumerresponsestopriceandratestructurechangesusingbillingdata—typicallyfocusingononeorasmallsetofutilities—withthegoalofestimatingpriceelasticitiesofdemand(e.g.,
Olmsteadetal.,
2007;
Olmstead,
2009;
MansurandOlmstead,
2012;
Baerenklauetal.,
2014;
Wichmanetal.,
2016;
El-Khattabietal.,
2021;
Smith,
2022)
.Incontrast,Icharacterizetheefficiencycostsofprevailingwaterpricingpracticesusingadecadeofwaterandwastewaterratestructuresmatchedwithadministrativedataonmunicipalfinancesformorethan700municipalutilities.Tomyknowledge,thedataassembledinthispaperisthemostextensivepaneldatasetofwaterutilityratestructureslinkedwithutilitycostsandrevenues.Thesedataallowmetoestimatemarginalcostsandcompareratestructure
characteristicsacrossutilitiesinvariedgeographicregions(i.e.,coastal,mountainous,urban,
6Privateorfor-profitbutnotmunicipalwaterutilitiesaretypicallyregulatedbystateutilitycommissions.
7ResearchhasaddressedthecomplicationsofIBRsbecausetheygeneratekinksinconsumerbudgetconstraints
(Hanemann,
1984)
.Structuraldiscrete-continuouschoicemodelshavebeenappliedtoestimatepriceelasticitiesofdemandforwaterandelectricity(e.g.,
HewittandHanemann,
1995;
Olmsteadetal.,
2007;
Olmstead,
2009;
Baerenklau
etal.,
2014;
Szabo,
2015;
McRae,
2015)
.However,researchershavealsoquestionedwhetherconsumersunderstandnonlinearratestructuresandprovidedevidence,forbothelectricityandwater,thatconsumersmightrespondto
average,ratherthanmarginal,prices(Ito,
2014;
Wichman,
2014;
BrentandWard,
2019;
Shaffer,
2020)
.Othershave
arguedthatconsumersdorespondtomarginalpriceifthechangesarelargeenough(NatarajandHanemann,
2011)
.
5
rural)andwithheterogeneousservicepopulations.Importantly,thedatasetincludeshundredsofsmall-andmedium-sizedwaterutilitiesthatarerarelyevaluatedineconomicsresearchdespitetheircentralroleindeliveringessentialservicestoresidentsoutsideoflargemetropolitanareas.
Renzetti
(1992),
Renzetti
(1999),and
Timmins
(2002b)areamongthefewpapersthatevaluate
theefficiencyconsequencesofmunicipalwater(andwastewater)prices,buttheyarebasedonnow-outdateddatasetswithlimitedgeographicortemporalscopeanddonotaccountfortherecent,increasingprevalenceofnonlinearratestructuresdespitethetrade-offsinherentinfixedversusvolumetricpricingdecisions.
2Conceptualframework
Inthissection,Ilayoutamodelofrate-settingformunicipalwaterutilities.Myapproachadoptsthegeneralframeworkof
LevinsonandSilva
(2022),whichanalyzestheredistributivepotential
ofnonlinearelectricitypricingbyextendingaformalmodelof
Coase
(1946),butIrefocusiton
theparticularsofmunicipalwaterandwastewaterutilities.
2.1Thehousehold’sproblem
Considerahouseholdthatmaximizesutilityoverwaterconsumption,wi,andanumerairegoodxi,wheresuperscriptsindexhouseholds(i=1,...,n).ThehouseholdearnsincomeMi,whichissubjecttoamarginaltaxrateofτ≥0andalump-sumgovernmenttransfergi(bothofwhichthehouseholdtakesasgiven).Thehouseholdspendsincomeonwater(atmarginalpricepwithafixedservicefeet≥0)andthenumerairegood(withpricenormalizedto1)inthepresentperiod,
leadingtothebudgetconstraintpwi+t+x=(1?τ)Mi+gi.Leti≡(1?τ)Mi+gi?ti
representafter-taxresidualincome.Thehousehold’sproblembecomes
maxui(wi,i?pwi).(1)
wiThehousehold’sfirst-orderconditionis
Thisconditionimplicitlydefinesdemandforwaterandthenumerairegood:wi(p,i)andxi(p,i)=?pwi(p,i).Pluggingthesedemandequationsintotheutilityfunctionresultsinthefollowingindirectutilityfunction:vi(p,i)=u(wi(p,i),xi(p,i))foralli=1,...,n.
2.2Thegovernment’sproblem
Thegovernmentchoosesprices,fixedfees,andmarginaltaxratestomaximizethesumofindirectutilityhouseholdsreceive.Itsroleisthefirstpointofdeparturefrom
LevinsonandSilva
(2022)
6
becausethemajorityofUSwaterutilitiesarepublicentitiesownedandoperatedbymunicipalgovernments;theyarelargelynotprivate,regulatednaturalmonopolies,suchasnaturalgasorelectricutilities.Thisdistinctionhasimportantimplicationsforbudgetbalancingandfixed-costrecoverythatIexploredirectly.
ThegovernmentmanagesawaterutilitythathasfixedcostsFandper-unitcostsc.So,thegovernment’stotalcostofsupplyingW=ΣiwiunitsofwaterisF+cΣiwi.Thegovernmentmustbalanceitsbudgeteachyear,resultinginthefollowingbudgetconstraint:
whereG=Σigiaretotalgovernmentaltransfers.Theleft-handsideofthisequationisgovern-mentalrevenue;theright-handsideisgovernmentalexpenditure.
2.2.1Aself-sufficientwaterutility
First,assumethegovernmentchoosespandtbuttreatsτasfixedandexogenousandthatτΣiMi=G,sothatitfocusesonlyonbalancingrevenueandcosts.ThisresultsinthesimplerbudgetconstraintΣi[t+pwi?cwi]=F,whichreducestothebaselinecasein
Levinsonand
Silva
(2022)
.Thesolution,outlinedindetailin
AppendixA,providesthecanonicalresultthat
priceshouldbesetequaltomarginalcost(p=c).Substitutingthisresultintothegovernment’sbudgetconstraintresultsinsettingfixedfeesequaltoaveragefixedcosts,or,t=F/n.
Ifthegovernmentcaninsteadsetindividualizedprices,pi—whichmightreflectpricediscrim-inationacrosscustomersorheterogeneousmarginalpricesacrosstheconsumptiondistribution(i.e.,IBRs)—theprimaryinsightdoesnotchange.Theoptimalpricingrulewhenindividualizedpricesarefeasibleresultsintheconditionthatpi=cforalli,orthatallunitsofconsumptionshouldbechargedthesamemarginalprice.Thisresult—thatmarginalpriceshouldbeequalacrosscustomersanduses—shouldbeuncontroversialtoeconomistsandsuggeststhatanypric-ingstructurethatdeviatesfrommarginal-costpricingwillbeinefficient.
Borenstein
(2012)claims
thatIBRsforelectricityhavenocostbasis,asIBRsassigndifferentmarginalpricestodifferent
customers,leadingtodifferentincentivestoconsumewater.8
LevinsonandSilva
(2022)additionallyshowthatifthegovernmentcaresaboutequityand
cansetindividualizedfixedservicefeesandmarginalprices,thenmarginalpriceshouldstillbesettoequaltomarginalcost,forallhouseholdsanduses,andthefeeusedtoredistributeincomecompletely(i.e.,ifhouseholdsdifferonlyintheirincomes,thenitwillbeusedtoequalizeincomeacrossallhouseholds).Ofcourse,fullyredistributingincomethroughautilitybillisanimpracti-calresult,althoughmilderversionsofthissolutionmayaidinredistributionwithoutsacrificing
efficiency.9
LevinsonandSilvausethisasapointofdeparturefromoptimaltwo-parttariffsto
8Hanemann
(1997),however,arguesthatIBRscouldbesupportedbyacostargument,inasmuchasblockrate
structures
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無(wú)特殊說(shuō)明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁(yè)內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒(méi)有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒(méi)有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文庫(kù)網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 2024年度店鋪?zhàn)赓U與廣告投放服務(wù)合同3篇
- 2024版定制化軟件開(kāi)發(fā)采購(gòu)合同樣本3篇
- 2024年度知識(shí)產(chǎn)權(quán)轉(zhuǎn)讓合同-著作權(quán)轉(zhuǎn)讓3篇
- 2024年度房地產(chǎn)抵押貸款估價(jià)服務(wù)合同3篇
- 2024年標(biāo)準(zhǔn)車輛運(yùn)輸服務(wù)合同模板版B版
- 2024版信息技術(shù)服務(wù)采購(gòu)合同模板3篇
- 2024年度股權(quán)轉(zhuǎn)讓合同:某企業(yè)之間關(guān)于股權(quán)轉(zhuǎn)讓的具體規(guī)定3篇
- 2024年度生態(tài)環(huán)保項(xiàng)目投資擔(dān)保借款保證合同范本3篇
- 2024年度事業(yè)單位合同制工人聘用合同書(shū)3篇
- 2024年數(shù)據(jù)中心基礎(chǔ)設(shè)施安裝分包合同2篇
- Unit5 Our New rooms Lesson1(教學(xué)設(shè)計(jì))2024-2025學(xué)年重大版英語(yǔ)五年級(jí)上冊(cè)
- 2024至2030年中國(guó)采棉機(jī)行業(yè)深度調(diào)研及投資戰(zhàn)略分析報(bào)告
- 英語(yǔ)B級(jí)單詞大全
- 智能充電站轉(zhuǎn)讓協(xié)議書(shū)范本
- 清醒俯臥位通氣護(hù)理專家共識(shí)
- 人教版部編道德與法治九上1.1《堅(jiān)持改革開(kāi)放》說(shuō)課稿
- 低壓不停電換表接插件技術(shù)規(guī)范
- 2024版烏魯木齊二手房買(mǎi)賣(mài)合同
- 跨學(xué)科教學(xué)設(shè)計(jì)-《軸對(duì)稱圖形》
- 腦卒中患者深靜脈靜脈血栓預(yù)防
- DLT 5210.5-2018 電力建設(shè)施工質(zhì)量驗(yàn)收規(guī)程 第5部分:焊接
評(píng)論
0/150
提交評(píng)論